(OPE-L) [Jurriann] Re: simple commodity production

From: Gerald A. Levy (Gerald_A_Levy@MSN.COM)
Date: Fri Sep 10 2004 - 08:59:25 EDT


----- Original Message -----
From: "Jurriaan Bendien" <andromeda246@hetnet.nl>
Sent: Friday, September 10, 2004 7:22 AM


Jerry,

A final reply on this vexed issue. You write:

You misunderstood my point:  I did not suggest that was a definition of
SCP; it is the commonly accepted definition of 'commodity' used by
economists, historians, anthropologists and others.

Reply:

Okay then, have it your way. The problem with these unspecified
"economists,  historians, anthropologists and others" is that they project
categories belonging to the bourgeois epoch back into history, in order
to trace the evolution of markets based specifically on cash economy.
But the elementary  form of a commodity, Marx insists, is a traded
labour-product which has a socially known and established value, a
use-value and an exchange-value, which does not presuppose money,
but only the knowledge that X amount of  tradeable object A is worth Y
amount of tradeable object B. Rather than  naturalise money and capital,
Marx aims precisely to show that trading  processes have a history
which goes beyond money and capital, which makes money and capital
historical categories, rather than ahistorical categories.
In neo-classical econmics, money-prices are always assumed, and therefore
no intelligible discussion of the development of exchange relations can take
place - that discussion is mostly relegated to anthropology. Neo-classical
economics has no more use for the categories value, use-value and
exchange-value precisely because it assumes cash economy and trade with
money-prices as a given datum.

You argue:

What I objected to was the historical claim that commodities and commodity
production existed in pre-capitalist *classless* societies --  a claim
that  is not supported by the weight of the historical evidence that I am
aware of.   Most of the rest of  Jurriaan's post rests on this
misunderstanding
of  the point I was making.

Reply:

A lot of anthropological research has been done on tribal societies which
are either stateless, classless societies, or proto-class societies, which
shows that surpluses were traded without use of money on the basis that X
amount of commodity A is known to be worth Y amount of commodity B, as an
ancillary activity to subsistence production. These findings generally
support Marx's hypothesis, that trade historically begins at the
boundaries of separate economic communities, and involves goods
which those communities cannot produce themselves, or not in sufficient
quantity and quality. Those exchanges refer to the most primitive forms of
simple commodity production which are the progenitors of market
economy.

You wrote:

Jurriaan's interpretation rests critically on the belief that where
there is production for barter there is commodity production.

Reply:

No, I do not say that, and my interpretation does not "critically rest on
that belief". Anthropologists know very well that bartering may occur on a
incidental, episodic basis, or occur on the basis of production explicitly
aimed at exchanging the products on the basis of known relative values. My
interpretation is based on understanding the evolution of the commodity
form itself, through increasingly more sophisticated forms of trade. At
least a sixth of the value of world trade nowadays takes the form of
counter-trade (or offset agreements), but obviously money does play a
role in it as valuation and accounting referent. Barter on that scale could
not easily occur without monetary valuations.

You wrote:

An (unstated) corollary of Jurriaan's position is this: if 'commodities'
existed in pre-capitalist classless societies, then there is every reason
to  believe that commodity production will persist under communism!
This is a position which some 'market socialists' might take comfort in,
but it is not a position which seems consistent with other stated
positions of Jurriaan.

Reply:

I do not see how this would follow at all. Communism is normally thought
of  as a form of world society in which, with highly developed productive
forces of labor, there is abundance of a type which enables the direct
allocation of resources according to need, without resorting to trade,
but on the basis of a collectivist morality of freely associated producers.
The possibility of that happening does not depend on the economy that
existed 15,000 years ago but on the development of technology and on
human development. But I could live with the idea that some trade might
still occur under communism. What I have stated previously is, that the
generalised hostility of "orthodox" Marxists to markets, and the absolute
counterposition of market economy and planned economy, is mistaken and
wrong. This hostility has its main origin in the Stalinist industrialisation
project  in the Russian republics, based on forced collectivisation and
forced labor, which aimed to resolve the "scissors crisis" affecting the
trade between industrial goods and agricultural goods, and subordinate
the peasantry to the rule of the Soviet polity. It is an hostility which
prevents any clear discussion of the pro's and con's of different kinds of
markets as instruments for allocating  resources, and how they could be
combined with social planning.

You wrote:

If commodity production  existed even before recorded history
in pre-capitalist classless societies and will continue to persist under
communism, then 'commodity' becomes natural and eternal.  The belief
myth  that commodities have always existed and will always exist is
asserted by some bourgeois economists but it is not a belief that Marxists
should be associated with.

Reply:

I do not see why that follows either. As I have said, the real point is to
understand the historical evolution of trade, from ceremonial gifts,
silent barter and casual/episodic trade as activities which are ancillary to
subsistence production, to increasingly more developed forms of commodity
trade, in which production for exchange becomes a specialized activity,
and ultimately begins to dominate social production. This insight is
essential to understand the process of market formation and market
integration, and it  means we should clearly distinguish between
pre-capitalist commodity production, and capitalist commodity production.
My main aim has been to show that the spurious Marxist controversy
about whether or not "a society of simple commodity producers" existed,
overlooks the real matter at stake: that capitalism is, as Marx says,
"generalised commodity production" (verallgemeinte Warenproduktion).
Generalised commodity production means that both the inputs and
outputs of production are all commodities (traded objects) which
means that labor-value rules production.  This however cannot exist
other than as the production of capital, precisely because the
generalisation of commodity production itself is dependent on the use of
money as universal equivalent, and as soon as the circuit C-M-C' gives
rise to the circuits M-M' and M-C-M', then commodity exchange becomes
a means for capital accumulation. In turn, that gives rise to a new class,
the bourgeoisie, which is able to make labor itself an object of capital
accumulation, and eventually is able to subordinate the whole production
process to the requirements of capital accumulation. Even so, we should
distinguish clearly between the existence of capital and wage-labor, which
originates and develops in the interstices of the old modes of production,
and capitalist society based on the production of capital, which emerges
only after a lengthy process of the growth of trade, and all sorts of
social upheavals and class struggles. I'll leave it at that.

Jurriaan


This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Sat Sep 11 2004 - 00:00:02 EDT