From: Jurriaan Bendien (adsl675281@TISCALI.NL)
Date: Fri Mar 24 2006 - 16:15:39 EST
Hi Jerry, Well, contrary to a determinist Marxism, I think Marx never denied the vital importance of beliefs, feelings and mentalities; but I think that a materialist interpretation of history would require locating the basis or background of those beliefs, feelings and mentalities in social existence and in practical life, and how the former react back to the latter, influence that. And I think Marx had no "rational expectations" model based on the self-interested economic actor - there are always at least two "logics" in his writing - the logic that individual subjects or groups consciously claim to apply, and the overarching "logic" of the social totality in which they are situated, or, to put it differently, the "logic" of the given objective situation and the "logic" of the individual subjects or groups who may rightly or wrongly imagine all sorts of things about that situation, as they act within it. The relationship between the two logics could however be difficult to assess, and often one really has to participate in the situation to understand it well, and avoid sociologisms (though, sometimes one can see things by standing outside the situation better, than the people completely involved in it - there are no epistemic warranties here). Hegel contrasts with Marx/Engels here, insofar as Hegel often tries to deduce these logics speculatively, while Marx/Engels believed they had to be verified experientially (it was incidentally Engels who mainly drafted the section on Feuerbach in the German Ideology manuscript, Helmut Fleischer says - so much for the Engels-bashers). Another issue is, that the "beliefs" I mentioned may lack any profound rational basis, indeed this is precisely why they are beliefs. People may act partly on the basis of instinct, intuition, impressions, superstitions etc. (didn't Keynes also refer to "animal spirits"?). And what may appear as irrational from one perspective of what rationality is, may appear as quite rational, if the matter is looked at from a different angle. The case I mentioned of Dutch savings behaviour, perfectly illustrates how, when economics cannot explain real economic behaviour, it is forced to resort to extra-economic factors (e.g. national psychology). Duncan Foley has a delightful article on the notion of rational "economic agents" here: http://cepa.newschool.edu/~foleyd/ecagent.pdf Postmodernism of course casts doubt on our very ability to fathom the rationality of social behaviour, in which case we are left only with a story, a narrative, which may refract a reality in some limited way. But in truth, of course, people are normally pretty rational about the most important practical issues in their lives, and very resistant to propaganda which does not accord with their real experience of life, even if this happens not to be well-captured in economic theory. Der Spiegel has an interesting, if somewhat cynical, article on the "crisis feeling in France" which comments: "Lack of security -- "précarité" -- is what everyone is talking about. The student protest movement has no charismatic leader and no vision for society's future. Many of the demonstrators and strikers are not members of any political organization or party. "Many of them have never demonstrated before," one student says. But the new type of employment contract introduced by Villepin has created a common front of dissent. One flyer distributed by the students of Nanterre asks: "How are you supposed to find an apartment and build a future for yourself when you can lose your job from one day to the next?" In other words, the life plans the young protesters perceive to be under threat are perfectly middle class." http://service.spiegel.de/cache/international/spiegel/0,1518,406157,00.html Daniel Bensaid, for his part, commented on the French "crisis feeling" as follows: "The present movement is directly based on a social question - the destruction of workplace regulations and the generalised casualisation of employment, which is common both to youth in education and to workers. (...) In 1968, the unemployed were counted in tens of thousands in a period of great expansion, so students had no worries about the future. Today six million people are either without work or casually employed, and over the past few years we have experienced a series of social defeats, despite the big movements of 1995 over public services, and of 2003 over pensions. So the balance of forces that the present movement has intervened in is, at the outset, very unfavourable." http://www.socialistworker.co.uk/article.php?article_id=8550 You see here how Bensaid tries to apply Marx's "two logics" in his analysis - the subjective impulse, and the objective "balance of forces" (Kraftsverhaltnisse, rapports des forces). With all this "précarité" around, it's of course easy to slipslide into either a voluntarist subjectivism or a fatalist objectivism. I'm personally more skeptical about Bensaid's sociological notion of "balance of forces" though, because frequently a dramatic event (e.g. 9/11, the French riots, the EU referendum etc.) shows that the real balance of forces is not what people thought it was, i.e. it might be more a speculation or extrapolation, based on analogies with the past, and it might indeed be counterproductive to people asserting themselves; it is through asserting themselves, that the real power relation becomes known, but that relation can also shift very rapidly, and take people by surprise. In other words, it is not so much the balance of forces which determines the conflict or campaign, but rather the conflict or campaign which sorts out what the balance of forces really is. In general, of course, you usually don't pick a struggle, unless you think you have a chance of winning, but then again you might not have any choice about struggle, and whether you can win, may be conditional on entering into the ring ("You don't know what you haven't tried"). This is why I think the notion of "balance of forces" itself is crucially ambiguous, and really not very informative. When you read Bensaid's erudite rambling discourse "Marx for our times" (Verso books), funny thing is that while he mentions a "science of the concrete particular", he does not analyse the subject of power in any profound way at all. Francis Fukuyama cites an example of just how quickly perceptions about the "balance of forces" can change: "A lot of the neo-conservatives drew the wrong lessons from the end of the Cold War and the collapse of communism. They generalized from that event that all totalitarian regimes are basically hollow at the core and if you give them a little push from the outside, they're going to collapse. Prior to the fall of the Berlin Wall, most people thought that communism would be around for a long time." http://www.spiegel.de/international/0,1518,407315,00.html It's a sort of brutally vulgar analysis. So much for the pitfalls of reasoning by historical analogies though... Jurriaan I want to be straight, I want to be straight I wanna create a place of my own in the welfare state wrr, gonna be good, wrr, gonna be kind It might be a wrench, but think of the stench that I'm leaving behind I want to be straight, I want to be straight Come out of the cold, and do what I'm told and don't deviate I wanna give, I wanna give, I wanna give my consent I'm learning to hate all the things that were great when I used to be bent! - Ian Dury and the Blockheads
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Sun Mar 26 2006 - 00:00:06 EST