Dear Friends: Since Gerald brought up Marc Linder, here is a brief review of his 2000 book on overtime law in the U.S. It is a book that should be of interest to all Marxist labor historians, labor law scholars, and anyone interested in worktime issues. Cheers, Paul Burkett --------------------------------------------------------------------- "Moments Are the Elements of Profit": Overtime and the Deregulation of Working Hours Under the Fair Labor Standards Act, by Marc Linder. Iowa City, Iowa: Fanpihua Press, 2000. Paper, $15.00, Pp. 524. Marc Linder is widely known among radical political economists as the author (with Julius Sensat) of Anti-Samuelson (1977); but among students of U.S. labor law and labor history he is more familiar as a leading scholar on the evolution of overtime law under the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 (FLSA). The present book is a culmination and synthesis of Linder's FLSA-related work over the last two decades. The first of the book's four chapters outlines the legislative history leading up to the FLSA, including a detailed treatment of state-level overtime laws. This chapter also establishes the two main dynamics of twentieth-century overtime law in the U.S., both of which involve responses by capital to worktime initiatives: (a) the pressure, where overtime laws are inevitable, to press for overtime pay regulations as an alternative to outright restrictions on the length of (daily or weekly) worktime; (b) the pressure to limit the effective coverage of overtime pay laws. Linder's entire analysis may be viewed as a study of how these two dynamics interacted in complex ways. For example, although overtime pay regulations (especially time and a half wages) were designed in part as a disincentive to extended work days (hence as a kind of compromise under dynamic (a)), the emasculation of these regulations (dynamic (b)), combined with other factors like the growing fixed costs of hiring new workers, eroded any such disincentive. Linder emphasizes the adverse effects, from a working-class standpoint, of overtime even with premium pay. Overtime work (as opposed to hiring new workers) increases the reserve army of unemployed, exerting downward pressure on wages, ceteris paribus. Competition among employed workers for limited overtime also tends to create a situation where both extended worktime and the wage packet with overtime become the standard, producing a further downward pressure on hourly wages similar to the effects of piece-rate systems. Such inter-worker competition can only erode working-class solidarity. As Linder shows, however, the exact forms and effects of these pressures are only determined in the ebb and flow of economic, legislative, and judicial conflicts. Indeed, a key point emerging from Linder's overall analysis is that organized labor's post-World War II accommodation to these pressures has had an extremely damaging effect on working-class conditions and politics. This accommodation involved not only an acceptance of overtime pay as an alternative (in reality fictitious) to limits on worktime (contrasting with the struggles of earlier labor leaders like Gompers for outright caps on worktime), but also an acquiescence to the progressive exclusion of many non-union workers from the FLSA's overtime and minimum wage provisions -- to the point where currently only about 60 percent of U.S. workers are covered. The detailed analysis of the exclusions begins with Chapter 2's discussion of "pseudo-managers," i.e., workers not covered because they are (supposedly) mainly engaged in supervisory and other managerial tasks rather than regular production work. The fast food industry in particular has profited greatly from the super-exploitation of "assistant managers" who work long stretches of effectively uncompensated overtime on fixed weekly salaries. Along with such functional exclusions, quasi- managerial and other white-collar workers have been subjected to "salary test" rules stipulating that workers whose weekly wages (pro-rated over 40 hours) exceed a certain level are not covered by the FLSA's overtime pay regulations. Linder documents how, through inadequate nominal adjustments over the years, the relevant test salaries have gradually shrunk to levels at or below the equivalent hourly minimum wage under the FLSA (242). Chapter 3 deals with the struggle over the Portal-to-Portal Act of 1947, which placed strict limits on the applicability of overtime pay to the time spent in preparatory and/or post-work activities conducted in the workplace. The controversy emerged initially from the mining industry where workers were subjected to long and often treacherous commutes between the gates of the mine and the actual point of mineral extraction; but it became of more general relevance as factories grew in size during World War II, producing greater walking times between factory gates and work sites. Linder shows how capitalists and their government representatives used the portal controversy to further limit FLSA coverage through, inter alia, statutes of limitations on back wages and damages payable as a result of suits filed under the FLSA, limits on class-action (as opposed to individual or closed-end group) FLSA-lawsuits, and the legal sanctification of "custom or practice" with regard to "down time" (based on particular industry or enterprise conditions and bargaining histories, however asymmetric worker-boss power relations may have been). In treating the relationship of small enterprises and their employees to the FLSA, Chapter 4 first demonstrates that Congress's initial intent, in exempting workers in smaller businesses from blanket coverage, was mainly to limit coverage to workers engaged in interstate commerce -- the fear being that the courts might otherwise strike down the FLSA on state's rights grounds. This motivation is evident from the stipulation that individual employees engaged in interstate commerce would still be covered even when the smaller businesses employing them were exempted from blanket coverage. (Naturally this created a cottage industry of arcane legislative and judicial opinion- writing as to exactly what constituted participation in interstate commerce.) Over the years small business associations and their congressional supporters manufactured the myth that the FLSA had always intended to exclude small business as such on economic grounds. This line of thinking helped pave the way for the Unfair Labor Standards Amendment of 1989, which raised the floor on enterprise coverage to $500,000 in annual sales, effectively excluding millions of workers especially in the construction industry. Linder demolishes, both logically and empirically, the economic rationales behind the 1989 Amendment. Overall, Linder's analysis of overtime pay regulation suggests that "workers and unions" should reject "profitability and consumer demand as the social economy's highest ordering principles" in favor of human development as registered in social caps on worktime (207). For starters, "depriving capital of its status as the sole authorized interpreter of the market's commands" as regards worktime requires "an explicit economic theory and unbiased empirical studies," as well as a "democratically organized discussion" based on "honesty and comprehension on the part of legislators and interest and intelligence on the part of intervening participants," all of which "have been conspicuously absent" (207, 511). More positively, the ongoing conflict over FLSA overtime provisions is an opportunity for Marxists to take a higher (and popular) ground in policy discussions. Linder's book is a rich and highly readable resource for those interested in pursuing this political-intellectual project (in addition to being required reading for specialists in U.S. labor history and labor law). PAUL BURKETT Department of Economics Indiana State University Terre Haute, IN 47809 ecburke@isugw.indstate.edu
This archive was generated by hypermail 2b30 : Sun Jun 02 2002 - 00:00:07 EDT