From: michael perelman (michael@ECST.CSUCHICO.EDU)
Date: Thu Dec 23 2004 - 13:15:22 EST
Sorry, I put up the wrong sections. _Replacement Investment Patterns_ Because the installation of long‑lived capital goods is likely to disrupt production, one might expect that long‑lived investments would be installed or significantly upgraded during contractions when plant and equipment is used less intensively (S. Moss, 1984, p. 297). Because of the British capital shortage in the years immediately following the Second World War, the ratio of capital disposals to capital acquisition stood more than 50 per cent lower than it was in the 1950s (Butler, 1960, p. 261). More dramatically, 'in the panic of 1920‑1921, Ford closed down for six weeks, cleared his plants of obsolete equipment, and then proceeded to improve working methods and layout and to install modern equipment. Also in 1920, the Lelands spent $4,249,000 for special machine tools to produce postwar Lincolns' (Wagoner, 1968, p. 126; see also p. 136). Most firms did not respond to the depressed economic conditions in this fashion. Commentators took notice of Ford's policy only because it seemed so exceptional. Firms do most of their replacement when competitive pressures compel them to do so (Boddy and Gort, 1971, p. 182; S. Moss, 1984, p. 297). As a result, productivity increases tend to be associated with business failures (Montgomery and Wascher, 1986). For example, during the Depression, the quantity of machine tools shipped in the US dropped sharply from a peak of 50,000 units in 1928 to a low in 1932 of 5500 but the equipment that was shipped during the Depression was predominantly for replacement rather than expansion (Wagoner, 1968, p. 137). Prior to the 1930s, machine tool manufacturers used to purchase the best available equipment. In the wake of the Depression, 'machines were replaced only when they clearly could not do the work required' (Wagoner, 1968, p. 136), perhaps because the intensification of competition on the demand side was compensated by reduction in wages and a higher value placed on liquidity. During the Depression, firms weeded out inefficient plant and equipment, creating a much newer capital stock (Staehle, 1955, p. 124). By 1939, one‑half of all manufacturing equipment in the US that had existed in 1933 had been replaced (Staehle, 1955, p. 127). Thereafter, business produced as much output as a decade before with 15 per cent less capital and 19 per cent less labour (Staehle, 1955, p. 133). French productivity also improved noticably during the Depression (Aldrich, 1987, p. 98, citing Carr'e, Dubois and Malinvaud, 1972). Similarly, in the recessionary period of 1982‑4, only 20 per cent of West German manufacturers replying to IFO's investment survey gave capacity expansion as their motive for investment; 55 per cent cited rationalization (Anon., 1985a, p. 69). Once the economy begins to prosper, scrapping returns to its normally low level. During expansions, firms tend to increase the proportion of investment devoted to long‑lived capital of the sort that expands capacity (Boddy and Gort, 1971; see also Mairesse and Dormont, 1985). During these periods firms feel little pressure to replace obsolete plant and equipment (Bleany, 1985, p. 77). Costs are less concern than the opportunity to expand capacity. For example Schmenner reports that space constraints and poor plant layout are much more important than labour costs in explaining why plants move to new locations (Schmenner, 1980; see also Boddy and Gort, 1971). In recent times, fashionable theory explains investment by factors that affect the supply of capital, especially taxes. Supposedly the interaction between inflation and the tax structure theoretically made long‑lived investment relatively less economical (Auerbach, 1979). Tannenwald emphasized the combination of the tax code and the rising cost of structures, along with the changing mix of economic activities, as an explanation for the declining share of investment used for structures (Tannenwald, 1982; Ott 1984). This result was based on the official construction cost index for industrial and commercial structures derived from the price structure for single family homes, which rose almost 50 per cent faster between 1974 and 1981 than the corresponding deflator for producers' durable goods (Eisner, 1982, p. 106). However, industrial and commercial structures' costs were rising much more slowly than the costs of single family homes (Allen, 1985). Moreover, inflation could make industrial and commercial structures relatively more attractive as an inflation hedge, just as was the case with residential structures during the early 1970s. Finally, recall Eisner and Chirinko's finding that firms are insensitive to tax incentives (see Ch. 3). The tax argument cuts both ways. Although taxes might make consumption more attractive than investment, tax shelters might tend to channel a greater portion of investment in office buildings and other structure‑intensive activities, such as oil and gas drilling (Garner, 1986). The pattern of resale prices for structures suggests the importance of the benefits which the tax codes offer to investment in structures. The estimated depreciation rates of assets, based on the market prices for second‑hand capital, implies that the aggregate equipment stock is quite close to that of the Bureau of Economic Analysis. In contrast, a similar estimate for the market value of non‑residential structures was more than 30 per cent greater than the official estimates (Hulten and Wykoff, 1981a; and 1981b). These estimates might suggest that favourable tax treatment of office buildings promotes a buoyant resale market for real estate compared with the market for other second‑hand capital goods, which are less easily transferred to other uses. For example, in 1984, commercial real estate investment was more than 50 per cent higher than its 1979 level. Construction by the industrial sector, which is presumably more specific than commercial real estate, was less than 74 per cent of its 1979 level (Magdoff and Sweezy, 1985, p. 7; see also Garner, 1986). Other explanations are possible. The divergence between the results for equipment and for buildings could be explained by the peculiar estimating procedures used (Harper, 1982). It could also be the result of the lemon effect for equipment (discussed above), but this phenomenon, if it is operative at all, would probably not be sufficient to explain the full difference. _The Contradictory Nature of Demand Management_ Notwithstanding the complications associated with the empirical application of the q‑theory, the q‑ratio approach suggests a promising way to analyse replacement investment which throws a great deal of light on the post‑war history of the US. Common sense suggests that a buoyant economy with high asset values encourages the purchase of new capital goods, thereby promoting economic efficiency. Further reflection reveals that the same policies which lifted the q‑ratio also impaired efficiency in the long run by inhibiting the replacement of existing investments. Such policies are especially dangerous when combined with a weakening of the wage pressures which might otherwise compel business to replace capital. Much obsolete plant and equipment is operated, or at least stands ready to operate, alongside modern operations. In the US automobile industry during the late 1960s the productivity per employee of the top quarter plants was 2 1/2 times as productive as the lowest quarter (Melman, 1983, p. 184). Such disparities in productivity became even more extreme during the 1970s as a result of the continued deferral of scrapping. Carter's input‑output study of US industry suggests the same phenomenon. She set up a linear programming problem to minimize the total factor requirement in order to produce the 1958 vector of output using either 1947 or 1958 technology in each industry. In 14 of 76 sectors, the 1947 technology was superior (Carter, 1970, p. 171‑2). Sato and Ramachandran note replacement was less vigorous in these 14 industries (Sato and Ramachandran, 1980, p. 1007). Much of the 1958 technology in these industries might simply be the 1947 technology after 11 years of operation. Indeed, the rate of productivity of the US economy seems to have fallen despite evidence that the rate of improvement in new capital goods has accelerated in recent decades (McHugh and Lane, 1987). The average capital good is now being used more intensively than it was in the past. A 1976 follow up survey of a 1929 US Census of Manufacturing query about the hours worked by fixed capital found that, from 1929 to 1976, the average work‑week of fixed capital rose by about 25 per cent, or 0.475 per cent per annum. During this same period the ratio of fixed capital to manufacturing output fell by 45 per cent (Foss, 1981 and 1981a and 1985). In part, this trend is associated with more extensive shift work, rising from 22 per cent of the workforce in the 1960s to 28 per cent in 1972‑5 (Bosworth, 1982). The US data for 1973‑8 are unchanged (Hedges and Sekscenski, 1979). The rise in shift work in the US is far milder than in France, where the per centage of French workers in shift work rose from 28 to 77 per cent in metal production between 1957 and 1974; from 8 to 39 per cent in machine building; and from 34 to 50 per cent in textiles (Lipietz, 1982, p. 223). Even after adjusting for plant hours, the ratio of fixed capital to manufacturing output ratio dropped by 30 per cent. Other things being equal, one would expect a trend toward a rising capacity utilization, as shift work became more common. Yet the evidence does not support the existence of such an increasing trend because of a changing distribution of the utilization patterns of capital. The most modern plants are used intensively, while many obsolete plants are used little, if at all. A similar pattern exists in manufacturing in the Less Developed Economies, but there it is explained by the difficulty in importing spare parts, a problem that does not affect plants in the Developed Economies (Kibria and Tisdell, 1984, p. 64). Many of the less utilized plants represent what I will describe later as phantom capacity. Again, the data are not clear enough to prove my point decisively, but they are consistent with the idea of an economy carrying an increasing load of obsolete equipment during the post‑war period. The perverse long run relationship between the q‑ratio and productivity will figure largely in what follows. When the q‑ratio is high, firms tend to install new investment alongside the old facilities instead of replacing existing investments with more efficient plant and equipment. More recently, a growing scepticism about the efficacy of expansionary economic policies has been responsible for a perception of uncertainty that makes older, depreciated capital goods more attractive. This process is relatively new, dating back to the decline in competition, which began in the late nineteenth century. Previously the US economy was characterized by rapid replacement brought on by high wages and rapid technological advance (see below). Beginning with the deferred replacement policies of the twentieth century, scrapping became limited until slowdowns of crisis proportions caused massive waves of scrapping such as occurred during the Great Depression, when much of the excess capacity from the First World War boom was wiped out. After the Second World War, the process of accumulating excess capacity began anew. Renewed scrapping began only after a long period of stagnation, extracting a dreadful human toll in the process. Consider the relationship between the q‑ratio and capital replacement. All q‑ratios do not move uniformly. With the onset of prosperity, capital goods devoted to some specific cyclically sensitive uses might become relatively more valuable. Their q‑ratios would also rise relative to others. Why would firms not take advantage of the high market prices for existing capital goods by selling them rather than maintaining them in operation? In many cases, firms did just that. At other times, they did not. In the first place, existing capital goods can serve as the basis for loans or the issuing of equities. Additionally a firm that sells its capital goods earns a fixed amount on the second‑hand goods market, but it loses the option to profit from the use of that good should some new opportunity arise. The more uncertain the environment is, the more likely that such an opportunity will actually occur. Consequently firms might rationally hold on to capital goods even when their salvage values exceed the expected present value of the cash flows earned from their operation by a considerable amount (McDonald and Siegel, 1986, p. 711). Since managers, unlike shareholders, are more concerned with expansion than the rate of return on investment, they may be inclined to hold on to existing capital goods. Donaldson's survey of Fortune 500 companies led him to conclude: 'the financial objective that guided the top managers ... [was] the maximization of corporate wealth. Corporate wealth is _that wealth over which management has effective control_ ... Corporate wealth differs considerably from the shareholder value which is central to much financial theory' (Donaldson, 1984, p. 22). Management might want to hold on to plant or equipment, even if it were technologically obsolete, because it appears to add to the value of the firm. Despite my earlier insistence on the existence of active second‑hand capital goods markets, transaction costs introduce a wedge between the value of capital goods to a firm and its value on the resale market. These transaction costs discourage the marketing of existing capital goods. Delivery lags may explain why firms might not replace highly priced used capital goods. Additionally the market for some second‑hand equipment becomes weaker during prosperous times. For example, old tractors are traded in for new models when times are good, thereby diminishing second‑hand prices relative to new capital costs (Reid and Bradford, 1983, p. 329). Lacking sufficient incentive to sell such equipment, old tractors may be kept on for later contingencies. During downturns, farmers, like other managers, frequently conserve liquidity by continuing to operate existing equipment. In the process, the tractor stocks age. Once boom times return, sales of new tractors expand once again. The potential tax burden of good years reinforces this pattern. In reality, tractors are atypical capital goods since their prices are pro‑ rather than counter‑cyclical, partly because the pride that farmers take in their machinery makes tractors into a quasi‑consumption good. Recall the high second‑hand capital prices of the 1960s. Most other types of obsolete capital goods can only be operated at high levels of demand because the capital services that they provide are not as homogeneous as those provided by tractors. A huge number of outdated adding machines are not equivalent even to a modest computer. I will turn to a more important explanation for the continued use of old and seemingly obsolete plant and equipment. I will frame this analysis in terms of a revised interpretation of the q‑ratio. -- Michael Perelman Economics Department California State University michael at ecst.csuchico.edu Chico, CA 95929 530-898-5321 fax 530-898-5901
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Sat Dec 25 2004 - 00:00:02 EST