From: glevy@PRATT.EDU
Date: Tue Mar 14 2006 - 09:31:51 EST
Hi Paolo, Yes, of course, Loren's writings are relevant. Years of reading messages forwarded from the "prudent bear" forecasting gloom and doom for capital was the context for many of my comments in this thread. Ar some point -- years on, in this case -- you have to ask for 'success criteria' to be identified. The article you are referring to is "COMMUNISM IS THE MATERIAL HUMAN COMMUNITY: AMADEO BORDIGA TODAY". Here's the section I _think_ you are referring to .... >>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>> The Lenin-Trotsky tradition divides the history of capitalism into two phases, separated by World War I, inaugurating the "epoch of imperialist decay". The theoretical sources of this theory come from the "monopoly capital" discussion prior to World War I: Hobson, Hilferding, Lenin. It was popularized for an epoch by Lenin's Imperialism. Capitalism in the heyday of the Second International looked different from the system described in Marx (it is important to remember that Vols. 2 and 3 only became available in the 1880's and 1890's; most socialist militants' relation to "Marxist economics" has come from Vol. I and more realistically from popular pamphlets like "Wages, Prices and Profits".) Capitalism seemed to be moving away from a "competitive" or "laissez-faire"' phase to a phase of cartels, monopolies, imperialism state guidance, the emergence of finance capital, arms races, colonial land grabs: all the elements Hilferding called "organized capitalism" circa. 1910. World War I marked the turning point. The Russian Revolution showed that, in Lenin's phrase, "the proletarian revolution lurks behind every strike", and the 1917-1921 period very nearly seemed to confirm that. Then came, after an ephemeral stabilization, 1929, world depression, fascism, Stalinism, and World War II, followed in turn by incessant wars of national liberation. Who, in 1950, could deny that this was the "epoch of imperialist decay"? These very real phenomenon cemented a whole world view, first codified in the early years of the Comintern: the continuity with the Kautskyian vulgar Marxism of the pre-1914 period, the "monopoly capital" characterization of the epoch, most ably expressed by Bukharin, Trotsky's theories of permanent revolution and combined and uneven development, and the Congress' characterization of the epoch as that of "imperialist decay". This, at least, was condensed expression of that heritage as it was recaptured in the best attempts of the late 60's and early 70's to relink with the revolutionary potential of the German-Polish-Russian corridor of 1905 and 1917-1921. This periodization of modern history allowed one to see the world "from Moscow in 1920" and this, again, made the unraveling of the history of the Russian Revolution and of the Comintern from 1917 to 1928 so central and so apparently full of implications. In that history was the philosopher's stone, whether Trotskyist, Schachtmanite, or ultra-leftist. This was the viewpoint of those who, into the mid-1970's, had no illusions about Social Democracy, Stalinism, or Third World Bonapartism, i.e who opposed them from the vantage point of revolutionary workers' democracy of the soviet/worker council variety. On one level, this seemed a perfectly coherent explanation of the world into the mid-1970's. Had not the highest expression of the revolutionary workers' movement taken place in Germany and Russia? Had not everything since been disaster and bureaucratic nightmare? Bordiga anticipated this attitude when he wrote, sometime in the 1950's, that "just because social evolution in one zone (by which he meant Europe and the U.S.) has come to the next to the last phase does not mean that what happens on the rest of the planet is socially of no interest". For this world view, (shared in that period by the author) what was happening on the rest of the planet was precisely socially of no interest. Who could seriously propose China or North Korea or Albania, or the national liberation movements and their states, as models for American or European workers? But such a view, while correct, was not adequate. WHY NOT? Because it ignored two realities already well underway in the mid- I 970's: the double movement of Third World industrialization and technology-intensive ("high tech") development in the advanced sector that were about to crash down around the Western working class movement, upon which the whole earlier perspective rested. In 1970, in the midst of Stalinist, Maoist and Third World euphoria over peasant-bureaucratic revolutions, it was right and revolutionary to look to the Western working class as the only class that could actually end class society. It was necessary to reject that Third Worldist hogwash then, as it is necessary to reject its (quite enfeebled) remnants today. But what has changed since then is of course that de-industrialization in the West and industrialization in the Third World (two sides of the same coin) have created real workers' movements in the Third World itself, South Korea being the most recent important instance. Into the mid-70's the world looked pretty much like what could be extrapolated from the early, heroic Comintern view sketched above. The countries that were the core of world industry in 1914 (Western Europe, the U.S. and Japan), were still the core. In terms of the earlier discussion, if a country had not been "internally reorganized" by the 1860's it wasn't going to be in the "industrial club" in 1914 and still wouldn't be circa 1975. Further, the percentage of workers in manufacture in the advanced industrial counties, which had peaked at circa 45% in Germany and England circa 1900-1914, was still close to that figure for the advanced capitalist zone as a whole in the early 70's. What had changed in the interim? Clearly, the advanced capitalist world had gone from a (very rough) breakdown of its work force, in 1900-1914 of 45% in industry, 45% in agriculture, 10% in white-collar services, to 40-45% in industry, 5-10% in agriculture, and 40-45% in white-collar services (not to mention the creation of a large arms sector that had only barely come into existence around the turn of the century). What did this indicate? It indicated that the "story" of capitalist development was as follows. In 1815-1914 the phase of "classic" or "competitive" capitalism, the system had primarily transformed peasants into workers, at lest in England, the U.S., France and Germany. In the post-1914 period (in reality beginning circa 1890) the new phase of "organized" capitalism, "monopoly" capitalism, the "epoch of imperialist decay" continued to deplete the rural populations of the Western world (and Latin America, the Caribbean, southern Europe and Africa), but to accomplish what? Instead of continuing to expand the industrial work force, it used the greatly increased productivity of a stagnant percentage of the work force to support an ever-growing white collar "service sector" (and arms production). But to return to the basic theme, Communist Parties start to erode and be super by integrated Social Democratic type parties precisely when the agrarian population of the country in question is reduced to a trivial (5-10%) of the work force. This is what has happened, for example, in France and Spain in the last 15 years. This is what has not happened in Portugal, precisely because small producer agriculture remains a very significant percentage of the Portuguese work force. This is the backdrop to the transformation of the PCI. It is what happened long ago in northern Europe and the United States. It is, finally, the strict parallel to the problems encountered in Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union when the "extensive" phase of accumulation is completed and it is time to move to the intensive phase which the West arrived at through the crisis of 1914-1945. In short, from enlightened absolutism in the 17th century to Communist Parties in the 20th century, the problematic is that of the extensive phase of accumulation - the transformation of peasants into workers. The ultimate implication of this is that a society is only fully capitalist when a trivial percentage of the work force is employed in agriculture, i.e. that a society is only fully capitalist when it has moved from the extensive/formal to the intensive/real phase of accumulation. This means, in short, that neither Europe nor the United States in 1900 were as capitalist as the socialist movement thought they were, and that the classical workers' movement, in its mainstream, was first and foremost a movement to propel capitalism into its intensive phase. In sum, capitalism means first of all the agrarian revolution. The agrarian question has had multiple meanings in the history of the international left. It has arisen in connection with the peasant revolutions that accompanied the French and Russian revolutions; the capitalization of agriculture in the U.S. South through the Civil War; the agrarian depression after 1873; the emptying of the European countrysides after World War II. Undoubtedly, these are seriously distinct phenomena that should not be lumped together cavalierly. But let us focus on intensive accumulation linked to the reduction of the agrarian workforce to 5-10% percent of the population as the definition of a "fully capitalist" society. A fully capitalist agriculture is an American-style mechanized agriculture. The "agrarian question" in this sense, was not solved in France in 1789 but in 1945-1973. The connection between agriculture and intensive accumulation in industry is the reduction of the cost of food as a percentage of the worker's bill of consumption, creating buying power for the consumer durables (such as the automobile) at the center of 20th century mass production. Let us summarize, and then return, one more time to Bordiga and the neo-Bordigists. Vulgar Marxism was an ideology of the Central and Eastern European intelligentsia linked to the workers' movement in a battle to complete the bourgeois revolution (Second and Third International Marxism). Its parallel to pre-Kantian, pre-1789 bourgeois materialism is not the result of an "error" ("they had the wrong ideas") but a precise expression of the real content of the movement that developed it. That content makes sense ultimately in the framework of a periodization of capitalist history that complements the Lenin/Trotsky "epoch of imperialist decay" with the concepts of extensive/formal domination and intensive/real accumulation. The whole Lenin/Hilferding 2nd International theory of "organized capitalism" and "monopoly capitalism" is then, an occultation of the transition from extensive to intensive. The "official Marxist" outlook, therefore is the outlook of a nascent state elite, in or out of power, whose movement results in another form of capitalism (real domination) and calls it "socialism". What is compelling about such an analysis is that it avoids moralizing and offers a "sociological" explanation for an "epistemology". Once again it means that this social stratum that held an Aufklaerung form of materialism because it was a proto-state civil service in a development regime, and that its economics, codified in the Leninist theory of imperialism, were also the economics of that stratum. It is not real Marxism, because it tends to replace analyses of relations and forces of production with (ultimately Duehringian) analyses of "force". From Lenin and Bukharin via Baren and Sweezy to Bettleheim and Amin to Pol Pot (recognizing tremendous discontinuity and degeneration but also continuity) the 'monopoly capital" theory is the theory of state bureaucrats. It is fundamentally anti-working class. It sees the Western working class's reformism as the expression of super profits' from imperialism, and it obscures the difference of interests between the state bureaucratic elite and the peasant and working classes in the underdeveloped countries where it holds power. The French neo-Bordigists, specifically Camatte, showed that it was in Russia above all that Marxism, in phases, was transformed from a theory of the "material human community", a real movement that is "born" from mature capitalism into something that is "built" in backward proto-capitalism. This is seen by the contrast between the "Marxist position" on the Russian question developed by Marx in 1878-1883 and the Bolshevik polemic with the last phase of Populism in the 1890's. Whatever Marx may have entertained in his study of the Russian commune as the possible base for an immediate "leap" to communism, he never would have written, as Trotsky wrote in 1936, that "socialism now confronts capitalism in tons of steel and concrete". This is not to say that there is no basis for this productivist discourse in Marx's work; it is simply to say that the gulf that separates Marx from all 2nd, 3rd (and 4th) International Marxism is precisely that he is beyond "pre-Kantian" materialism and way beyond "monopoly capital" economics that both express a state civil service view of the world. In the battle between Lenin and the Populists in the 1890's, the battle to introduce this truncated 2nd International "Marxism" into Russia, the whole pre-1883 dimension of the Marxist analysis of the "Russian question", unearthed by Bordiga, was totally lost in a productivist chorus. The linear, mechanistic affirmation of "progress" that is the core of Enlightenment historical thought, which was taken over into a "stage" theory of history by vulgar Marxism, has no feel for the Russian agrarian commune, as Marx did. The Gemeinwesen (material human community) telos of communism is suppressed for productivism. Once in power, the Bolsheviks took the reproduction schema and categories of Vol. I of Capital and translated them into their manuals for economic planning without noticing that this was a "Ricardian" description of capitalism which Marx undermines in Vol. III. This paved the way for the "steeleater" ideology of the Stalinist planners after 1928. There is already a world between Marx and the 2nd International, and later the Bolsheviks, expressed in "philosophy" and in "economics", and these differences express different "social epistemologies" rooted in the outlooks of two different classes, the working class and the state civil service. It is in this sense that it is meaningful to say that the best of German Social Democracy and Russian Bolshevism are hopelessly entwined with the state. A renewal of revolutionary vision can no longer identify them as direct heirs, but as a detour whereby Marxism fused with a statist discourse foreign to itself. We, in the West today, unlike the revolutionaries of 1910, live in a totally capitalist world. There is no capitalization of agriculture to accomplish, no peasant' question for the workers' movement. At the same time, in the midst of a deepening world economic crisis of 1930's proportions, all the old revolutionary visions have evaporated , and the sense of what a positive world beyond capitalism would look like is less clear than ever. (Recent history provides many examples of negative alternatives.) Yet, when we understand that much of what is collapsing today is ultimately the legacy of the Enlightened absolutist state and its modern extensions, we can see that many of the conceptual tools in use until quite recently were tools for the completion of the bourgeois revolution, developed by movements ultimately headed by state civil servants, real or potential. By freeing Marxism of this statist legacy we can at last start to understand the world from the vantage point of "the real movement unfolding before our eyes" (Communist Manifesto). >>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>> Text from the Break Their Haughty Power web site at <http://home.earthlink.net/~lrgoldner> Is this what you had in mind? In solidarity, Jerry
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Wed Mar 15 2006 - 00:00:01 EST