From: glevy@PRATT.EDU
Date: Wed Apr 19 2006 - 07:47:08 EDT
Mediumi - Artikkeli - MarxIT Mediumi 1.5 30.04.2003 Tapio Mäkelä *M a r x I T* - materialism meets vapour ware Jukka Heiskanen & Jorma Mäntylä (eds.): MarxIT. Informaatiokapitalismin kriittistä tarkastelua. [MarxIT. A critical approach to informational capitalism.] Helsinki: Karl Marx-seura 2003 Had the investment analysts of the late 1990s read their Marx properly they might have reconsidered investments into companies, which instead of having their value tied to the effective production of assets and surplus value, were selling vapour ware (1), imaginary products and future prospects. MarxIT - Critical Examinations into Information Capitalism, edited by Jukka Heiskanen and Jorma Mäntylä, is a new collection of essays (in Finnish) that looks critically at the new economy, the concept of the information society, and the "battle" between proprietary software industry and the free software and open source movements. The book is successful in pointing out where Marxist analysis is valid in relation to IT, but not so rich in actually applying writing by Marx or later Marxist theorists. Perhaps the title of the book could have been "CastellsIT", since it is rather the information capitalism by Castells, which is looked at more carefully and critically. The discourse of new economy and attached neo liberalist notions of flexible labour, which writers such as Castells and Himanen have valorized in The Hacker Ethic, is successfully critiqued by Tere Vadén and Joachim Bischoff. Bischoff points out how in the "new economy" employees are often required to behave as if they were business partners, and thus required to adjust to rapid shifts in the increasingly fluctuating markets (37). Finnish statistics on the increased polarisation of income since the mid 1990s would support his arguments. The embodied labour of the IT industry has been worse exploited than the labour of late 20th century mechanical industry, for instance. In Information society theories the networks empower workers and challenge old-fashioned corporations, that is in theory. *Software hegemony and its counter forces* Many essays in the collection provide interesting overviews of political implications of software economy, production, and alternative social organisation of software development. One of the themes across the book is to discuss increased power of shareholders in relation to nations and citizens. According to the German sociologist Joachim Bischoff, the ITC has boosted instability through stimulating faster economic rotation and capital growth (35). The power of nation states has become more challenged, but not insignificant, contrary to the claims of Castells. Jorma Mäntylä's essay on Microsoft's monopoly position in the context of Marx and Gramsci is perhaps the best read in the collection, and exemplifies the increasing involvement of the US in political decisions on the software market. Mäntylä points out that Marx predicted in the mid 19th century how free competition leads to centralisation of capital and eventually to monopolies. He also compares Gramsci's analysis on the crisis of the Fordist production with the "bursting of the bubble" in the IT-sector, where the productivity of intellectual labour rather than that of the physical labour of individuals has been maximized. Mäntylä supports the view by Nicholas Garnham, according to whom the concept of Information society is a theoretical failure due to internal contradictions and having no empirical evidence to back it up. Garnham claims that its popularity in political discourse can only be understood if Information Society is an ideology. One of the main contradictions that Garnham outlines is the relationship of information economy with Marxist value theory. If value is not measured against a market, where supply and demand is tied to a regulated use of material and workforce, but instead to a market based on immaterial value, the global market becomes extremely risky. "In economies that produce and exchange knowledge, stable relations between work and value crumble" (51). According to Garnham, the social creativity of knowledge requires its free flow unrestricted by intellectual property rights. Here he sees a major problem in the attempts to turn universities into knowledge sales corporations (51). Indeed, if one considers Information society as a hegemonic view on contemporary society, then one could extend the Gramscian analysis that Mäntylä proposes, to further consider what are the counter discourses to it. Is Open Source software, for instance, a counter discourse that the proprietary IT hegemony will attempt to include into itself? Or is Microsoft such an empire as often described in popular accounts that it is able to maintain its position through practicing power rather than subtly becoming a software ideology? The decision by one G.W. Bush nominated judge Colleen Kollar-Kotelly not to break up Microsoft monopoly is considered by Mäntylä as a radical shift in the bourgeois ideology. Instead of free competition, the Microsoft court decision suggests that monopolies can be accepted as "the normal state of the affairs". The court decision also gave US government and military a possibility to influence Microsoft software. Is the US information capitalism in fact approaching a form of communist practice? One could further discuss the bipolar nature of such capitalism, where freedom is at the forefront of both corporate and state rhetoric, but far from practice from the citizen's or end user's point of view. *Owner value melting into the air* Capitalist bipolarity can also be sensed in the attempts to maintain an opposition between proprietary and free software code. Editors Mäntylä and Heiskanen argue that it is not far fetched to analyse conflicts and contradictions of the Internet in the context of a battle between "commonly used" and exchange value oriented, capital controlled technology, and between real "general work" and "estranged" science (23). In the book it is perhaps this analysis, which brings Marxist value theory to the "heart" of the software industry. How can an industry prosper, if it does not have enough "general work and intellect" compared to work and technology controlled by cetntralised capital? According to Pertti Honkanen there is nothing new in capitalist production also utilizing free resources, such as open code. Honkanen points out that the Marxist value theory cannot undermine Linux and free software, which also protest against the value form and product form. He suggests that Castells' notion of value making being a product of the financial market is difficult to accept in the context of Marxist value theory. Marx wrote about speculative mania, when the process of work is only a nuisance for nations racing towards added value without labour. Honkanen rightly argues that "expectations of "owner value" melt into air, if they are not grounded in real addition in value, which in turn cannot happen without a work process" (65). If monopolies aim at homogenizing the market, and artificially maintaining a particular price level, it is no surprise then that Microsoft and open source movement are in conflict. Tere Vadén in his essay on free software movement and its social implications suggests that owning code or freedom of code favour different kinds of social lives. (89, see also his essay in mediumi) In as much as I agree with the notion by Carolyn Marwin and the one implicitly included in Vadén's argument that histories of technology are sums of their uses, I must question the limits of "social" in relation to software code. For most end users the difference between free and proprietary software is whether one has to pay for it or not. New social formations in relation to the code (software based P2P services are a different issue than code) are primarily open for programmers, system administrators, and the expert end users capable of discussing with the right vocabulary, "the code lingo". The promise of communities that develop software best suited for them can only be met by long-term development efforts or by public investments into such processes. Within media art and music composition, for instance, there are already free software tools developed within various networks. There is very little evidence however that the development itself, the work of making code for shared tools, would have led to all-together distinct social formations IRL (in real life). One would hope that a sharper distinction would be made between the imagined professional networks of interest, and user cultures and subcultures that evolve around a particular new media environment/tool/software. *Contradicting freedoms* Besides the terms social and community the other term that Vadém could have assessed more critically in the book is "free". In an interview by Vadén on a question that addresses, especially in small language groups like the Finnish cultural domain, music and literature as areas where copyright is still needed, Richard Stallman replies: "The current system is very bad for publishing for these people as well. To replace this system with a non-system would not make the situation much worse from their point of view. I believe that support systems that are based on voluntary action could work as well as the current one - even better" (110). In this respect, if free software is looked at as a individualistic practice (and also partially as hedonistic since hackers are defined by Stallmann as those who enjoy playful intelligence), the freedom of it starts to sound very similar than the US rhetoric on freedom and opportunity. In the Finnish context, copyright legislation by the state is seen by the cultural sector and by the journalists as the cornerstone for their livelihood (which Vadén pointed out in his question to Stallman). Media conglomerates have been lobbying for restrictions to or an end to an author based copyright in Finland and internationally. Particularly US companies would like to see an end to an author and artist driven copyright legislation. That would have grave consequences particularly in minority cultures like Finland. This commentary is not to critique the intentions behind elevating free or open source software in their analysis, but to be critical in what social and political implications are in fact involved in anti-copyright freedom and what kinds of social practices are generated through code. Jussi Silvonen considers Linux and other free software to be both a part of IT revolution process and differ from it radically at the same time. In his essay he analyses the four freedoms of Free Software by Stallman. His analysis of Stallman's third clause on freedom to distribute modified versions of software for free or for a fee is very interesting. From consumer rights perspective, Silvonen writes, the user becomes the real owner of the software, and its use value exceeds that of its exchange value. "It is precisely this third freedom that places free software into continuous conflict with the market economy. Also, the following thought by Marx is opposed: "(o)nce the commodity has become the general form of the product, then everything that is produced must assume that form". Playfully one could say that Microsoft is portrayed in this respect as the most vehement Marxist by not agreeing to accept any other social formation for software than that of the product."(122; original quote of Karl Marx from Capital. A critique of Political Economy. Volume 1) The collection of essays is based on a seminar by Karl Marx association et.al in May 2002. Hence it is understandable how the collection is not so coherently looking at Marx and IT. For example, Harry Nick's essay on technology development in DDR is interesting, but does not "interface" very well with the rest. It also seems that the combination of Marx and IT has produced a "communality" of only male writers, and a book cover that I guess falls into the realm of digital social realism. *References* 1) Vapour ware was coined by Peter Lunenfeld in his book Snap to Grid, A User's Guide to Digital Arts, Media, and Cultures. Cambridge Mass.: The MIT Press, 2000. MarxIT. Informaatiokapitalismin kriittistä tarkastelua. Toim. Jukka Heiskanen & Jorma Mäntylä. Helsinki: Karl Marx-seura, 2003. For more information: <http://www.marx-seura.kaapeli.fi/> marx-seura@kaapeli.fi
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Sun Apr 30 2006 - 00:00:06 EDT