From: Jurriaan Bendien (adsl675281@TISCALI.NL)
Date: Tue Feb 20 2007 - 19:19:21 EST
You are correct, I didn't take a position. I didn't take a position because due to unfortunate circumstances I never got to research it as it ought to be researched and write a story about it as it ought to be told for my audience, i.e. carefully convey the real meaning of what happened and how people experienced that, good and bad. And usually I don't like to take a position, unless I feel that I have inquired into it sufficiently. I used to regard the New Zealand state as basically imperialist, but if I say that, what does it mean? You have to explain specifically what it means, what the implications are. Anybody can toss around labels, my job is to understand what it really means. I can sketch a few things though. By the way, David Bedggood did publish a book, called "Rich and Poor in New Zealand: a critique of class, politics and ideology" (1980) it was a sociological Marxist primer. And he published a number of articles. But I was a bit doubtful of his understanding of economics and history. **************** An "intermediate country" was a category acknowledged by the Communist International in its resolutions (from around 1926 I think, see the volumes edited by Jane Degras). An intermediate country would be a country that was neither clearly a colony nor a semi-colony, nor clearly an imperialist country, but transitional between them, i.e. a half-industrialised dependent country. The central question was, in whose interests the state mainly acted - local capitalists or foreign capitalists. The classical Communist argument was, that the domination of the world market by the rich countries largely blocked the development of poor countries; an international division of labour emerged, in which the poor countries could develop industrially or otherwise, only insofar as they serviced the needs of the rich countries (agricultural and mineral exports etc.). The local elite in poor countries was in cahoots with the elite in rich countries, but otherwise had little interest in developing their own country in a balanced way. It was therefore held to be impossible for the poor countries to develop and industrialise, or acquire independence, other than through a Communist revolution and the conquest of state power by the local workers and peasants. And if the imperialist states had carved up the world into "spheres of influence", the corollary was, that all countries of the world could be classified according to their place in these spheres of influence. The phenomenon of imperialism/colonialism is an enormously complex topic however, on which there is a very large literature, and what I read of it, inclined me to "unorthodox" view of it. Lenin showed a shrewd political insight into it, but some of his propositions about it cannot be sustained in the light of the facts, and this is also welldocumented by economists and historians. Different authors disagree about even the most basic concepts involved (what is imperialism?) and they differ in terms of the questions they ask, to which the concept of imperialism is supposed to be the answer. Imperialism was originally simply a bourgeois descriptive concept, with the positive connotation of spreading civilisation internationally, but it acquired a critical, radical meaning from the time of Luxemburg and Lenin onwards. It has both political and economic dimensions, but not only that - it also has cultural and legal/ideological, and even psychological/spiritual dimensions. In the wake of the colonial revolutions and decolonisation process during and after world war 2, the concept fell into disrepute in bourgeois circles, and indeed became counterproductive to foreign investment projects. Thus, the official line in the US is that "we aren't imperialist, because we have no colonies and do not aspire to an empire". This of course is not a very substantive argument from a Marxian point of view, insofar as legally possessing colonies is not essential to the Marxian concept of imperialism. The American state sees its international role as fostering healthy business development in the world, and keep order, and therefore its foreign policy can only be a force for good. Hence America has a natural right to intervene in any nation in any way deemed appropriate. This gives rise to the leftist notion of "empire" (Negri & Hardt). Broadly, imperialism describes the "domination" of a country, a nation or a people by another (or several others), asserted by economic, military, political-legal, cultural or ideological means. The development of the dominated society is therefore largely controlled or directed by the dominating society, which sparks off political movements that seek liberation from that domination and its ideological justifications, racist, religious or otherwise. Capitalist imperialism is rooted in the quest for market expansion, international business competition and the control over strategic resources or territory, justified with more or less racist or religious interpretations, theories of economic benefits, or arguments about "civilising missions". This brief definition may be unexceptionable, but the first problem you have there is that Marx never systematically developed a theory of international trade and international relations, although he wrote a considerable amount about international relations (e.g. India, Ireland, the USA, Mexico...). His viewpoint was often rather ambivalent, often very specifically oriented to the circumstances of different countries, and sometimes ethnocentric - imperialism was in his view both the source of gruesome oppression of foreign peoples, and also a source of progress, insofar as it enabled "modernisation", i.e. insofar as it eradicated obstacles to the development of the "productive powers of labour" ("Produktivkrafte", a concept which he borrowed from Adam Smith) and assisted the unification of the world. In the Communist Manifesto he stated how "the bourgeoisie had to nestle everywhere" in making new trading relations, and already in the Grundrisse he had described how market expansion fostered an enormous amount of new social relations and contacts among people the world over. However he did not yet research the accumulation of capital on a world scale, talking rather modestly about "'my sketch of the genesis of capitalism in Western Europe". ********************** New Zealand was in some ways an exception that proved the rule. To borrow from the blurb of Michael King's history, "New Zealand was the last country in the world to be discovered and settled by humankind. It was also the first to introduce full democracy. Between these events, and in the century that followed the franchise, the movements and the conflicts of human history have been played out more intensively and more rapidly in New Zealand than anywhere else on Earth." On 28 October 1835, the Declaration of Independence of New Zealand was signed by a loose confederation of Maori tribes, organised by the British resident James Busby. This document recognised Maori independence. Five years later the Treaty of Waitangi was signed, which ceded the independence (recognised by King William IV of the United Kingdom) of Maori to the British Crown. New Zealand was originally a sub-colony of New South Wales, but in 1841 it was created a colony in its own right. From the 1840s, New Zealand was clearly a settler colony, importing all kinds of manufactures and exporting farm products mainly to Britain (although a modest manufacturing sector developed, even in the 19th century). There wasn't any particular class structure at that time, and indeed the settlers (mainly skilled workingclass people from the UK) had quite a strong egalitarian ethos. Marx refers to Wakefield's theory of "systematic colonisation" and even many of the streetnames for the four new settlements to be built were dreamt up by architects and draughtsmen in Britain - the layout for the initial four towns and many buildings was designed in Britain, and then built in New Zealand. In the case of Christchurch, for example, the planned township around the cathedral was accidentally sited on a swamp, so the swampland had to be drained first, which they did. But Wakefield's British theory (land to be purchased by the Crown from Maori - whose title to their own land was formally recognised - and sold off for a price at which settlers first had to do a lot of productive work, before they could earn enough to own it) did not really work, simply because the Crown was for a long time not in the position to exercise control over land sales and private annexations, or enforce property rights rigorously (limited self-government of New Zealand existed from 1852). And initially the settlers (mainly men) were vastly outnumbered by the Maori tribes, who were skilled fighters and eagerly adopted European technology and weaponry. The "land wars" of the 1860s and 1870s which resulted, were not simply a fight between white colonists and Maoris - they often involved conflicting interests between the Crown, the settlers, and different Maori tribes (who occasionally were also at loggerheads with each other). In some cases, the Maoris defeated the British army in battle, or they defeated each other, or they fought so hard the British retreated. Some controversy therefore remained about who actually won the land wars. But, basically the Maori tribes lost, especially in the sense that they lost more and more of their land, whether through annexation or through dubious deals. The numbers killed in the battles were not so great - but a lot more Maori died of European diseases that were previously unknown, suggesting to many at the time they would disappear or be completely assimilated. By the 1890s, New Zealand was a fully self-governing country with its own armed forces (previously local regiments had supported the British army), although formally still a colony depending on a trading relationship with Britain (imports of manufactures, exports of primary products). It introduced the universal franchise (meaning women, who were no longer in short supply, could vote) and important social legislation provided for measures in public education, health, welfare and above all pensions, funded primarily from taxes. This was the era of autocratic Prime Minister Richard Seddon, known better as "King Dick". Seddon was a strong supporter of the British Empire and preferential trade between British colonies. He was also noted for his support of New Zealand's own imperialist designs, and his hostility to the Chinese. Seddon believed New Zealand should play a major role in the Pacific Islands, as the "Britain of the South". He would have liked to conquer Fiji and Samoa, but in the end, only the Cook Islands came under New Zealand's control during his term in office (in 1901). A French lefty called Metin wandered into New Zealand around that time, and was astonished - he said, this is "socialism without doctrines" and he wrote a book about it. The Webbs also paid a visit to this socialistic wonderland, and the intellectual/parliamentarian William Pember Reeves waxed about "state socialism in New Zealand". That was all exaggeration, an incipient labour movement was only just growing up under the tutelage of a reformist state, but nevertheless all this happened 50 years before Europeans thought of the "welfare state" concept and suchlike. Real power was in the hands of the local oligarchy and the propertied classes. Mounted troops were sent off to the second Boer war in South Africa of 1899-1902, and at the outbreak of world war 1, the first thing the New Zealand state did was to annex German Samoa. Next, New Zealand contributed more than 100,000 troops and nurses to the imperial conflict, out of a population of just over a million (42% of the soldiers were killed, and the total casualty rate was 58%). It was during this time (1900-1914) that the first socialist and syndicalist organisations appeared within New Zealand, and the trade union movement began to grow strongly, particularly among mine workers; a united Labour Party was formed in 1916 and a Marxian Association was founded in 1918. There wer all kinds of radicalisms at that time. In 1901 New Zealand did not ratify the Australian Constitution, and rejected membership of the Australian Commonwealth. In 1907, New Zealand stopped being a Crown Colony, and got British dominion status. In 1919 Prime Minister Bill Massey co-signed the Treaty of Versailles giving New Zealand membership of the League of Nations, indicating thereby that New Zealand did have a degree of control over its foreign affairs. Massey like Seddon was unequivocally an imperialist, and fervently supported the British Empire. In 1926, the Balfour Declaration formally gave New Zealand control over its own foreign policy and military. Significant changes came about in 1935 when a Labour government was elected, which utilised the state apparatus to finance jobs for workers and guaranteed prices for farmers (the real unemployment rate in the Great depression was in the order of 25% of the workforce, and economic conditions had been so bad even the old bourgeois parties wanted some state intervention). The electoral system now favoured the working class. In terms of its policies, the first Labour Government was the most left-wing social democratic government anywhere in the world at the time, but it had also completely reconciled itself to capitalism by then - very different from the "glory days" of its foundation, when "the socialisation of the means of production and exchange" was still seriously considered, plans were mooted for land nationalisation etc. The great socialist speechifyer in the Labour Party was Harry Holland, but he died in 1933. The first Labour government had not heard much of Keynes, but they did everything Keynes said you should do, and much more, and the economy revived. The New Zealand Communist Party however advised in 1935 not to vote Labour or screw up the ballot paper, because Stalin had trained them in the idea that Labourites were "social fascists"... and their Comintern delegate did not return in time for the 1935 election with the new "United Front policy" from Moscow. The military trend continued in world war 2, when 140,000 soldiers were sent off to battle by the Labour Government, and about 12,000 were killed, the Malayan Emergency and then the Korean war, where a volunteer force involved about 3,700 soldiers (very few were killed, i.e. about 30). Since that time, New Zealand troops (with many Maori serving) have been involved in numerous international conflicts, often under the aegis of the UN but often in a more minor supportive role. The Statutes of Westminster 1946-47 allowed the New Zealand Parliament full legislative powers, extra-territorial control of the New Zealand military and legally separated the New Zealand Crown from the British Crown. In 1948, the New Zealand Parliament passed the British Nationality and New Zealand Citizenship Act 1948, changing New Zealand nationality law. From 1949 all New Zealanders became "New Zealand citizens". However, New Zealanders remained British subjects under New Zealand nationality law, until the Citizenship Act 1977 came into force. In 1953 NZ stopped being a Dominion, and became the Realm of New Zealand. The Constitution Act 1986 removed any residual power of the United Kingdom Parliament to legislate for New Zealand at its request and consent. The post-war economic strategy in New Zealand (already starting during the war) was one of promoting indigenous industrialisation, an internal market for locally produced manufactured goods, through state incentives and regulation, import and price controls, guaranteed prices, tariffs, deficit financing and the like. The idea was basically to use a portion of earnings from farm exports to stimulate a local manufacturing sector, shielded from foreign competition, that would provide jobs for a growing urban working class. The great intellectual defender of this strategy was William Ball ("Bill") Sutch, from 1951-1965 the secretary of the Department of Industries and Commerce. It worked fairly well during the "long boom" of the 1950s and 1960s, even although the terms of trade for primary products tended to decline (for each imported tractor, you had to produce more and more sheep, cattle and dairy products etc.). In fact, unemployment fell to near-zero, meaning that employers competed for employees, and that wages strongly increased, causing considerable "featherbedding" and absenteeism. The "golden years" came to an end in 1973 - Britain joined the EEC, there was a recession, profitability fell sharply, and Keynesian pump-priming mainly had the effect that producers raised their product prices - that led, with an "investment strike" from about 1977, to stagflation and sharply rising unemployment. This caused a lot of workers' strikes and industrial disputes for a whole decade. The Muldoon government tried to combat this by increasing state controls and by ambitious state-led industrial investment projects to develop natural resources (the "Think Big" projects), financed by foreign loans and joint-ventures. However the projects did not create the jobs promised, and their costs escalated. Muldoon was a shrewd politician, and he introduced many state policies to keep his voter base (including a state-funded universal superannuation scheme) but his authoritarian style eventually alienated the middle class and a lot of workers. By 1983, there was a rent freeze, a price freeze and a wage freeze, the economy stagnated, and the public debt had grown considerably. The Labour Government (the fourth) ousting Muldoon in 1984 then embarked on the most radical neo-liberal shock therapy in the OECD, deregulating and privatising everything in sight following IMF guidelines, abolishing most subsidies, and completely overhauling central and local government functioning, with full support of the big corporations that had emerged in the previous decades, and an important part of the urban middle class, who made big profits from it. In addition, they completely overhauled industrial relations legislation to wreck union power. This was called "Rogernomics", and it went into history as the "Silent Revolution" (Colin James's term). It was silent insofar as the amount of protest against it was very limited, stifled and rather incoherent. It wasn't a real revolution, insofar as the elites stayed where they were and got richer (many parliamentarians also became millionaires), but the cultural changes were enormous. Marketisation continued under subsequent governments, who negotiated more free-trade agreements, for example with Thailand and Singapore, Brunei and Chile. More such deals are in the making with China, Malaysia, Hong Kong and some Gulf states. The effect so far was basically that 1/3 of society was better off, and 2/3 of society were worse off. A gigantic transfer of income took place from the poor to the rich, and from New Zealand workers to foreign investors. Real wages declined absolutely, and then stabilised at a lower level, partly compensated for by imports of cheap consumer articles (cars, furnishings, appliances etc.) from East Asia etc. Real GDP growth stayed at 0-2% level. Public debt was reduced, but private debt (corporate debt and household debt) increased astronomically. The average household's debt is now close to 160 per cent of annual disposable income, and debt servicing now takes up 12 per cent of disposable income. That debt is owed mostly to foreigners. Total debt to foreigners is about 87 per cent of GDP. The current account balance is about 9 per cent of GDP in deficit. The private banking system is now owned/controlled mainly from Australia. Foreign direct investment (FDI) assets have risen about 700% since 1989 (mostly takeovers, not newly established enterprises), and in most of the main branches of economic activity, the big companies are now all foreign-owned or controlled. They employ about a fifth of the workforce. The foreign owners reinvest only about a third or so of their profits in New Zealand. In rough order of importance, the main foreign owners are Australia, USA, UK, Singapore, Japan, Netherlands, Hong Kong, Germany, Switzerland and Italy. Foreign owners now control 40-50% of the share market. Foreign-owned land in New Zealand now takes up a million hectares, or about 7% of the commercially productive land area, including a lot of commercial forest and farm land. Foreigners buy up land in scenic spots and build mansions and hobby farms on them, or golf courses etc. New Zealanders are supposed to be glad that foreigners are willing to invest, but many do not like it much. ******************** It is this contemporary situation which shapes the current debates about "New Zealand as a nation", "re-colonialisation", "imperialism" and so forth. The petty bourgeoisie and the new middle class are often very proud of New Zealand as a nation, and of "kiwi ingenuity", they write about it, and there is much more of a market these days for indigenous cultural products if you have the money. But the working class is very concerned about where the money is going to come from, since a lot of their lifestyle is based to a large extent on credit, and their fixed costs rise while their wages don't - bank fees and interest charges, telephone bills, power charges, rates, rents, necessaries etc. If you get lucky, you own a house or a mortgage on it, in which case you have an appreciating asset. Or you have a job that pays well. If not, you might have to hustle. There is a lot more hustling, swindling, corruption and screwing money these days. Being unemployed in New Zealand has not much point, unless you have kids, you're better off in Australia. Paradoxically the newfound "nationhood" (also blaring through in media propaganda) combines with one of the most purely capitalist, globalised economies in the world - really, New Zealand is more cosmopolitan than it was ever before, more attuned and sensitive to international trends than ever before. At the same time, it is very impressive how New Zealanders have humanly coped with economic adversity, and made the best of it. How the political debate will evolve depends partly on the state of the world economy. If there was a serious international recession for example, New Zealand is very vulnerable and would feel the effect immediately and severely, because there are few buffers in the society anymore against external shocks. On the one hand, one imagines there would be a frenetic spate of buyouts, on the other hand there would be a strong protest from local people whose lives are stuffed up, and who cannot emigrate. The New Zealand government aims to keep everything going, through promoting clever trading, and through promoting New Zealand as a country to do business in. It is hoped, for instance, that through closer economic relations with East Asia many problems can be prevented or resolved. But how the debate will go, also depends on the ongoing cultural controversies and on political organisation. The Labour Party, originally a broad, democratic workingclass party, mutated into a middleclass bureaucracy which really "screwed" the New Zealand working class over with its policies. The working class in New Zealand nowadays has no political representation. The mass political parties there are, are the parties of the wealthy (except perhaps the Alliance Party). Some critics feel New Zealand sold off its birthright as an independent nation for a mess of pottage, and see the clever "kiwi kulchur" marketing as just a facade. At any rate, New Zealand is slowly becoming "Asianized" and "Pacificised", meaning also people are less open about what they really think and feel. One New Zealander suggested to me: "really we have come full circle; we started out as a part of New South Wales, and that's exactly where we are going". Jurriaan
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Wed Feb 28 2007 - 00:00:08 EST