Re: [OPE-L] Imperialism in our century.

From: Dave Zachariah (davez@KTH.SE)
Date: Wed Jan 02 2008 - 06:15:30 EST


Here: http://www.lausti.com/articles/gulf/oil.html

I found it while searching for information about Matzpen.



> Where has Machover argued this?
>
>
> Paul Cockshott
> Dept of Computing Science
> University of Glasgow
> +44 141 330 3125
> www.dcs.gla.ac.uk/~wpc/reports/
>
>
>
> -----Original Message-----
> From: OPE-L on behalf of Dave Zachariah
> Sent: Tue 01/01/2008 10:10 PM
> To: OPE-L@SUS.CSUCHICO.EDU
> Subject: Re: [OPE-L] Imperialism in our century.
>
> Thanks a lot for your informative reply Paul.
>
> Paul C
> ------
> What do you mean by the last sentence Dave?
>
> Dave Z
> -----------
> What I meant to say was that the last one hundred years have been a
> period of proliferation of nation states, quite the contrary to what one
> would expect from an abstract capitalist logic of expansion alone.
>
> Paul C
> -------
> Remember that states are something quite different from capitalist firms.
> States are territorial organisations that appropriate a significant, often
> major, part of the surplus product in the teritories that they control.
> As such they have distinct interests as surplus appropriators.
>
> Dave Z
> -----------
> I fully agree with you here. What I was aiming at was to what extent is
> there a "class character of the state" and to what extent are
> inter-state rivalries driven by rivalries between capitals today?
>
> As for the class character of the state I think of it primarily from a
> juridical point of view: the state is "capitalist" if it is assigned to
> protect capitalist private property. Then it is a matter of degree of
> the influence capitalist interests can have over the state. If those who
> run the state apparatus come from the propertied classes or at least are
> steeped in its ideology there may be a direct influence. If not, there
> is always indirect influence that stems from the fact that the bulk of
> taxable incomes are generated in capitalist firms.
>
> If we take the major inter-state conflicts since the collapse of the
> Soviet bloc, I can't see that they were the result of competition
> between capitals. They are primarily driven by territorial interests but
> under the influence of certain capitalist interests. Moshé Machover has
> argued that the US involvement in conflicts in the Middle East has been
> driven by short-term capitalist interests and long-term territorial
> interests.
>
> 1. The short-term. To raise the price of oil and to win favourable arms
> contracts with the state. (This of course benefits a section of
> capitalist firms at the expense of the others.)
>
> 2. The medium-term. Control over international oil trade to make sure
> that it continues to be traded in dollars rather than euros.
>
> 3. The long-term. Control the Middle East's oil reserves, and therefore
> those rival states whose economies depend on it.
>
>
>
>
>
> on 2008-01-01 00:08 Paul Cockshott wrote:
>>
>>  Dave Z
>> -----------
>> However, there are two issues that I think lack analysis:
>>
>> What is the relation between the capitalism and the nation state,
>> especially once capitalism has reached a truly global scale? From a
>> purely abstract capitalist logic one would expect a decay of smaller
>> nation states and the formation of larger blocs of juridical and
>> military power, e.g. as the EU. But the reverse seems to be true.
>>
>> Paul C
>> ------
>> What do you mean by the last sentence Dave?
>>
>>
>> Dave Z
>> -----------
>> Given
>> the integration of global capitalism today I have a hard time to see
>> that the rivalries between capitals  themselves will translate into
>> rivalries between nation states (except for the case of state-capitalist
>> enterprises).
>>
>> Paul C
>> -------
>>
>> Could one not have argued the same thing in 1908?
>>
>>
>> Remember that states are something quite different from capitalist
>> firms.
>> States are territorial organisations that appropriate a significant,
>> often
>> major, part of the surplus product in the teritories that they control.
>> As such they have distinct interests as surplus appropriators. They are
>> typically controlled by the propertied classes within that territory,
>> but,
>> in parliamentary states, have also to respond to the interests of other
>> classes. They also have the power to create money, upon which power the
>> whole process of capital accumulation ultimately depends, since
>> capitalist
>> wealth is denominated in the money created by these states.
>>
>> It is quite exceptional for a state to be controlled by and in the
>> service
>> of 'capital' they are typically in the service of 'national interests'
>> and
>> influenced primarily by firms based in their territory. In recent
>> years the
>> UK state has come to approximate a state in the service of 'capital in
>> general',
>> but that reflects the particular preponderance of finance capital
>> within the
>> UK economy. Few other capitalist states approach this British level of
>> openness to
>> foreign capital.
>>
>> Consider the degree wo which the US state and the US currency are
>> dependent on German
>> Chinese and Japanese credit. The creditor states could, with
>> adjustment to their
>> internal policies remove these lines of credit.
>>
>> Kalecki teaches us that the mass of profit in a capitalist economy is
>> determined
>> by the sum of capitalist consumption, net investment and the trade
>> surplus.
>> The trade surplus that China runs with the US constitutes a huge boost
>> to
>> the profits of Chinese firms, even if from the standpoint of a rational
>> Smithean calculus, it constitutes nothing more than a huge loss, a
>> huge subsidy
>> to the US. From the standpoint of individual chinese firms the trade
>> surplus
>> is a big gain, it boosts their profits. From the standpoint of the
>> state however,
>> as personified by the state bank, it is of much more dubious benefit.
>> It causes
>> an accumulation of dollar holdings of increasingly perilous real  value.
>>
>> One response is to set up large state venture funds so that China can
>> convert these
>> surpluses into equity capital, but such equity capital need not be
>> invested in the USA.
>> Another response could be for the state to step up internal
>> infrastructure investment -
>> but with 50% of Chinese gdp currently going on investment there is
>> little room for this to go much further.
>> Alternatively the surplus could be expended as internal state spending
>> on either armaments or
>> welfare as happened in for example the UK during the 50s.
>>
>> But if these things happen, what position does that put the USA in?
>> Suppose that the financing available for the current US deficit of
>> some $700 billion
>> dried up.
>> Will it still be able to sustain its current level of imports of
>> manufactured
>> goods and oil?
>> What would be the implications for the US state if it could no longer
>> finance
>> anything near current levels of oil imports?
>>
>> The free market value of the dollar would decline much further than it
>> has already.
>> Costs of oil and manufactured goods in US shops would rise even more
>> drastically.
>> What would the implications of this be for political stability with
>> the state?
>> What would the implications be for the continued viability of the US
>> armed forces
>> if they could no longer afford the oil they currently use?
>>
>> These factors alone would seem to provide ample motivation for the
>> revival of
>> imperialism in its most classic form -- the seizure of territories
>> rich in raw
>> materials, first Iraq, then perhaps Iran, then Venezuela. If all these
>> countries
>> were under US occupation they would have to supply oil in dollars,
>> however depreciated
>> the dollar becomes on the world market.
>>
>>
>> We should not be using the imperialism of 1908 as our model, but the
>> imperialism of
>> 1938.
>>
>>
>> Paul Cockshott
>> Dept of Computing Science
>> University of Glasgow
>> +44 141 330 3125
>> www.dcs.gla.ac.uk/~wpc/reports/
>>
>


This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Thu Jan 31 2008 - 00:00:06 EST