[OPE-L] Nafta Should Have Stopped Illegal Immigration, Right?

From: Rakesh Bhandari (bhandari@BERKELEY.EDU)
Date: Sun Feb 18 2007 - 21:51:52 EST


February 18, 2007
The Nation
Nafta Should Have Stopped Illegal Immigration, Right?

By LOUIS UCHITELLE
THE North American Free Trade Agreement, enacted by Congress 14 years ago,
held out an alluring promise: the agreement would reduce illegal
immigration from Mexico. Mexicans, the argument went, would enjoy the
prosperity and employment that the trade agreement would undoubtedly
generate — and not feel the need to cross the border into the United
States.

But today the number of illegal migrants has only continued to rise. Why
didn’t Nafta curb this immigration? The answer is complicated, of course.
But a major factor lies in the assumptions made in drafting the trade
agreement, assumptions about the way governments would behave (that is,
rationally) and the way markets would respond (rationally, as well).

Neither happened, yet Nafta remains the model for trade agreements with
developing Latin countries, including the Central American Free Trade
Agreement, passed by Congress in 2005. Three more Nafta-like agreements
are now pending in Congress — with Panama, Columbia and Peru.

When Nafta finally became a reality, on Jan. 1, 1994, American investment
flooded into Mexico, mostly to finance factories that manufacture
automobiles, appliances, TV sets, apparel and the like. The expectation
was that the Mexican government would do its part by investing billions of
dollars in roads, schooling, sanitation, housing and other needs to
accommodate the new factories as they spread through the country.

It was more than an expectation. Many Mexican officials in the government
of President Carlos Salinas de Gortari assured the Clinton administration
that the investment would take place, and believed it themselves, said
Gary Hufbauer, a senior fellow at the Peter G. Peterson Institute for
International Economics in Washington who campaigned for Nafta in the
early 1990s.

“It just did not happen,” he said.

Absent that investment, foreign factories congregated in the north, within
300 miles of the American border, where some infrastructure already
existed. “Monterrey is quite good,” Mr. Hufbauer said, “but in a lot of
other cities the infrastructure is terrible, not even enough running water
or electricity in poor neighborhoods. People get temporary jobs, but that
is all.”

Meanwhile, Mexican manufacturers, once protected by tariffs on a host of
products, were driven out of business as less expensive, higher quality
merchandise flowed into the country. Later, China, with its even-cheaper
labor, added to the pressure, luring away manufacturers and jobs.

Indeed, despite the influx of foreign-owned factories, total manufacturing
employment in Mexico declined to 3.5 million by 2004 from a high of 4.1
million in 2000, according to a calculation of Robert A. Blecker, an
American University economist.

As relatively well-paying jobs disappeared, Mexico’s average wage for
production workers, already low, fell further behind the average hourly
pay of production workers in the United States, and Mexicans responded by
migrating.

“The main thing that would have stemmed the flow of people across the
border was a rapid increase in wages in Mexico,” said Dani Rodrik, an
economist and trade specialist at Harvard’s John F. Kennedy School of
Government. “And that certainly has not happened.”

Something similar occurred in agriculture. The assumption was that tens of
thousands of farmers who cultivated corn would act “rationally” and
continue farming, even as less expensive corn imported from the United
States flooded the market. The farmers, it was assumed, would switch to
growing strawberries and vegetables — with some help from foreign
investment — and then export these crops to the United States. Instead,
the farmers exported themselves, partly because the Mexican government
decided to reduce tariffs on corn even faster than Nafta required,
according to Philip Martin, an agricultural economist at the University of
California, Davis.

“We understood that the transition from corn to strawberries would not be
smooth,” Professor Martin said. “But we did not think there would be
almost no transition.”

A financial crisis also dashed expectations. One expectation was that the
Mexican economy, driven by Nafta, would grow rapidly, generating jobs and
keeping Mexicans home. The peso crisis of 1994-95, however, provoked a
steep recession, and while there was some big growth later, the average
annual growth rate over Nafta’s lifetime has been less than 3 percent.

The financial crisis struck just months after Nafta came into existence,
undermining, early on, the Mexican government’s ability to spend money on
roads, education and other necessary government functions.

“We underestimated Mexico’s deficits in physical and human
infrastructure,” said J. Bradford DeLong, an economist at the University
of California, Berkeley, and a Treasury official in the Clinton
administration.

But, he says, without Nafta the migration would have been even greater.
For instance, he says, there would not have been as much investment in the
north of the country.

Finally, the steady flow of Mexicans to the United States has produced a
momentum of its own — what Jeffrey Passel, a demographer at the Pew
Hispanic Institute, calls a “network effect,” in which young Mexicans
travel to the United States in growing numbers to join the growing number
of family members already here.

The upshot is that Mexican migration to the United States has risen to
500,000 a year from less than 400,000 in the early 1990s, before Nafta,
Mr. Passel estimates. Roughly 80 percent to 85 percent of immigrants are
here illegally, he says.

The peso crisis, recession, the network effect — their impact may have
been beyond anyone’s control, but not the assumptions about how the market
and the government would act.

“We have indeed had one disappointment after another on this score,” Mr.
Rodrik said, noting that the same assumption about government spending is
part and parcel of the agreements, now before Congress, with Columbia,
Peru and Panama.

While there is opposition to these proposals, it is mainly from Democrats
who want a better safety net for American workers who might be hurt.

The European Union, in contrast, assumes little about government spending
on the part of economically weaker nations joining it. The union itself
has hugely subsidized the improved services needed by entering countries
like Portugal, Spain, Greece and Poland, rather than leave financing to
the relatively meager resources of entering countries.

The money is used not only for public investment, Mr. Rodrik noted, but
also to subsidize companies setting up operations in the new countries and
to support government budgets.

“I am not saying Nafta was a bad agreement,” Mr. Rodrik said. “But more
than a trade agreement is required for countries to converge economically.
And Nafta has been viewed as a shortcut to convergence without having to
do all the other stuff.”


Copyright 2007 The New York Times Company


This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Wed Feb 28 2007 - 00:00:08 EST