Hi Rakesh, Thank you very much for your (4626) and your reconsideration of my interpretation. I am glad that you now seem to agree with more of my interpretation. Although there appears to be one important remaining disagreement: Marx's method of the determination of the value transferred component of the value of commodities. Let's see. 1. You now seem to agree that the cost prices that Marx took as given in the determination of the values and the prices of production of commodities in his tables in Chapter 9 of Volume 3 are equal to given quantities of money constant capital and variable capital, which in general are not proportional to the labor-values of the means of production and means of subsistence. Therefore, we agree that Marx did not make a mistake in his determination of prices of production; he did not "forget to transform the inputs" of constant capital and variable capital from values into prices of production (right?). However, now you seem to argue that Marx made the opposite mistake in his tables in Chapter 9: he made a mistake in the determination of the VALUE of commodities (rather than a mistake in the determination of prices of production). The mistake has to do with the transferred value component of the value of commodities. That is, Marx assumed in his tables in Chapter 9 that the transferred value component of the value of commodities is determined by the given constant capital, which in general is not proportional to the labor-values of the means of production. But (you argue) this is not true. The transferred value component of the value of commodities is instead determined by the labor-time embodied in the means of production. So what Marx should have done in these tables is a sort of "inverse transformation" from the actual money constant capital to the labor-time embodied in the means of production, in order to determine the value of commodities correctly. Furthermore, such an "inverse transformation" of the transferred value component of the value of commodities would in turn require a similar "inverse transformation" of profit into surplus-value, which would cause the total amount of surplus-value to change (right?). (Presumably Marx made a similar mistake with respect to variable capital, but this is not discussed in this post.) But Rakesh, why would Marx want to do this? Why would he want to assume that the transferred value is a hypothetical quantity in order to explain a hypothetical surplus-value? Why not assume that the transferred value is the actual quantity of constant capital in order to explain the actual surplus-value, as I think Marx did? I don't mean "actual" in the full sense. You are right that the three volumes of Capital abstract from many concrete aspects. I mean actual in the sense that the total magnitudes constant capital and the total surplus-value in Volume 1 are the same as the constant capital and the total profit in Volume 3. The total magnitudes of constant capital and total surplus-value in Volume 1 are not more hypothetical quantities in Volume 1 than in Volume 3, which then have to be transformed into the more realistic quantities in Volume 3. The total magnitudes in Volume 1 are the same as, are just as actual as, the total magnitudes in Volume 3. 2. The reason why the value transferred from the means of production is determined by the given constant capital, rather than the labor-time embodied in the means of production, is that the means of production have already been purchased by the given constant capital. As Marx put it (we will see the passages below), the means of production ENTER PRODUCTION AS COMMODITIES, i.e. as commodities with a CERTAIN PRICE, and have been purchased with a certain quantity of money constant capital. Therefore, the labor-time embodied in the means of production has already been expressed (or taken a definite social form) - however imperfectly - as the price of these means of production, or as the constant capital advanced to purchase them. Even though this advanced constant capital is not proportional to the labor-time embodied in the means of production, it is nonetheless this already determined social form (the advanced constant capital) that is transferred to the value of commodities. 3. This Marx's method determination of the transferred value component of the value of commodities, by the constant capital advanced to purchase the means of production, is especially clear in the important manuscript, "Results of the Immediate Process of Production", written in 1864. Here we find the following passages: "Since wheat, hay, cattle, seed of all kinds, etc. are sold as commodities ..., it follows that they ENTER PRODUCTION AS COMMODITIES, i.e. as MONEY. Like the products, and as their ingredients, the conditions of production are indeed themselves products and they too are thus reduced to commodities. And as a consequence of the valorization process they are included in the calculations as sums of MONEY, i.e. as the autonomous form of exchange value." (C.I.: 952; emphasis added) "Since, with the exception of the additional labor, the elements of the capitalist production process already ENTER THE PROCESS OF PRODUCTION AS COMMODITIES, i.e. with specific PRICES, it follows that the VALUE ADDED BY THE CONSTANT CAPITAL is ALREADY GIVEN in terms of a PRICE. For example, in the present case 80 for flax, machinery, etc. (C.I: 957; emphasis added) I think these passage say: since the means of production enter the process of production as commodities with definite prices, the value transferred from the means of production is ALREADY GIVEN in terms of these prices, or in terms of the constant capital advanced to purchase them. 4. Similarly, in Chapter 1 of Volume 3, the transferred value is again clearly determined by the given constant capital advanced to purchase the means of production. To pick one passage out of many: "We know from Volume 1 (Chapter 9, p. 320) that the value of the product newly formed, in this case 600, is composed of (1) the REAPPEARING VAULE OF THE CONSTANT CAPITAL of 400 spent on the means of production, and (2) a newly produced value of 200_ [T]he value of the means of production consumed, a total of 400, is transferred from these means of production to the product. This OLD VALUE REAPPEARS _ BECAUSE IT EXISTED PREVIOUSLY AS A COMPONENT OF THE CAPITAL ADVANCED. The CONSTANT CAPITAL that was spent is thus REPLACED by the PORTION OF COMMODITY VALUE THAT IT ITSELF ADDS TO THIS COMMODITY VALUE. It seems clear to me that Marx is saying here that what reappears in the value of commodities (i.e. what is transferred from the means of production to the value of commodities) is the constant capital advanced to purchase the means of production. 5. This intepretation of Marx's determination of transferred value is further supported by several key passages in Part 2 of Volume 3, in which Marx explicitly stated, and illustrated with algebraic clarity, that the cost price in Volume 3 that partly determines the price of production of commodities IS THE SAME AS the constant capital and variable capital in Volume 1 that partly determine the value of commodities. 5a. The first passage is on p. 263: "If we take it that the composition of the average social capital is 80c + 20v, and the annual rate of surplus-value s' = 100 per cent, the average annual profit for a capital of 100 is 20 and the average annual rate of profit is 20 per cent. For any cost price k of the commodities annually produced by a capital of 100, their PRICE OF PRODUCTION WILL BE K + 20. In those spheres of production where the composition of capital is (80-x)c + (20+x)v, the surplus-value actually created within this sphere, or the annual profit produced, is 20+x, i.e. more than 20, and the COMMODITY VALUE PRODUCED IS K + 20 + X, more than k + 20, or more than the price of production. In those spheres of production where the composition of capital is (80+x)c + (20-x)v, the surplus-value or profit annually created is 20-x, i.e. less than 20, and THE COMMODITY VALUE THEREFORE IS K + 20 - X, more than k + 20, or more than the price of production. Leaving aside any variation in turnover times, the production prices of commodities would be equal to their values only in cases where the composition of capital was by chance precisely 80c+ 20v." (emphasis added) Here Marx is clearly saying that the COST PRICE (K) IS THE SAME for both the value and the price of production of commodities. The only difference between the value and the price of production of commodities is whether surplus-value or profit is added to this same cost price. In the case of a commodity produced by a capital of average composition, the surplus-value added to the cost price is equal to the profit added to this same cost price, and hence the price of production of such an "average" commodity will be equal to its value. This equality of the value and the cost price of commodities produced with capitals of average composition IS POSSIBLE ONLY if the cost price is the same for the determination of both value and price of production. 5b. Marx repeated these same points in the next paragraph (pp. 263-64) and gave a simple numerical example: " I. 80c + 20v +20s. Rate of profit = 20%. Price of product = 120. Value = 120. II. 90c + 10v +10s. Rate of profit = 20%. Price of product = 120. Value = 110. III. 70c + 30v +30s. Rate of profit = 20%. Price of product = 120. Value = 130." Could it be clearer that the cost price is the same for the determination of both values and prices or production? What changes between values and prices of production is whether surplus-value or profit is added to this same cost price. 5c. The following paragraph (pp. 264-65) begins with the three sentences that Rakesh has emphasized in recent posts to support his interpretation: "The development given above also involves a modification in the determination of a commodity's cost price. It was originally assumed that the cost price of a commodity equaled the value of the commodities consumed in production. But for the buyer of a commodity, it is the price of production that constitutes its cost price and can thus enter into forming the price of another commodity." Rakesh has interpreted these sentences to mean that the magnitude of the cost price in the determination of prices of production in Volume 3 is different from the magnitude of constant capital and variable capital in the determination of values in Volume 1. But this interpretation is flatly contradicted by the two preceding paragraphs just discussed, and the passages discussed below, including the continuation of the same paragraph (as I have discussed in recent posts) in which Marx said that: "THE cost price of a commodity is a GIVEN PRECONDITION, independent of his, the capitalist's, production, while the result of his production is a commodity that contains surplus-value, and therefore an excess value over an above ITS cost price. As a general rule, the principle that THE cost price of a commodity is less than its value has been transformed in practice into the principle that ITS cost price is less than the price of production. For the total social capital, where price of production equals value, this assertion is identical with the earlier one that THE cost price is less than the value. Even though it has a different meaning for the particular spheres of production, the basic fact remains that, taking the social capital as a whole, THE cost price of the commodities that this produces is less than their value, or than the price of production which is identical with this value for the total mass of commodities." Marx does not say in these sentences that the magnitude of the cost price changes, but rather that THE SAME COST PRICE is first related to the value of commodities, and then is related to the price of production of commodities. This is especially clear in the last three sentences about the total social capital. 5d. Further textual evidence from these pages of Chapter 9 to support this interpretation has been discovered recently by Alejandro Ramos-Martinez (and discussed on OPEL; Alejandro, are you there?). Marx's original manuscript of Volume 3 (written in 1864-65) has recently been published in German for the first time in the authoritative Marx Engels Gesamtausgabe (MEGA) (unfortunately, this particular volume will not be included in International Publishers's 50-volume Marx-Engels Collected Works). Alejandro examined Marx's original manuscript, and discovered that, for some inexplicable reason, Engel's version of Volume 3 LEFT OUT A CRUCIAL PARAGRAPH which comes immediately prior to the paragraphs quoted above on pp. 263-65 of the Vintage edition. In this omitted paragraph, it is clearly stated, both in words and algebraically, that K IS THE SAME for the determination of both the value and the price of production of commodities. Part of this paragraph (translated from German by my Mount Holyoke colleague, Jens Christiansen) is as follows (emphasis added): "The cost price is, as we see, always smaller than the value of the commodity. The price of production can be smaller, bigger, or equal to the value of the commodity. THE VALUE OF THE COMMODITY = THE VALUE OF THE CAPITAL CONSUMED IN THE PRODUCTION OF THE COMMODITY PLUS THE SURPLUS-VALUE. If we take, as in the original development of the cost price (Chapter 1), cost price = value of the capital advanced in the production of the commodities, we have the following equations: value = cost price + surplus-value V = K + s or profit as identical with surplus-value or = K + p cost price = value - surplus-value or K = V - s price of production = cost price + profit P = K + p' calculated according to the general rate of profit = p'. We can see that again THE SAME K is added to the surplus-value on the one hand and to the average profit on the other hand to obtain respectively the value (V=K+s) and the price of production (P=K+p') of commodities. The only difference between the value and the price of production of a given commodity is the difference between the surplus-value contained in it and the average profit allotted to it. If the surplus-value is greater (or less) than the average profit, then the value is greater (or less) than the price of production. 5e. In Chapter 12 of Volume 3, Marx returned briefly to the point that the price of production of an "average" commodity is equal to its value, and stated again that, since the cost price is the same in the determination of both the value and the price of production of these commodities, and since profit is equal to surplus-value for these average commodities, the price of production of commodities of these commodities is equal to their value. "Yet this possibility in no way affects the correctness of the principles put forward for commodities of average composition. The quantity of profit that falls to the share of these commodities is equal to the quantity of surplus-value contained in them. For the above capital, with its composition of 80c + 20v, for example, the important thing as far as the determination of surplus-value is concerned is not whether these figures are the expression of actual values, but rather what their mutual relationship is; i.e. that v is one-fifth of the total capital and c is four-fifths. As soon as this is the case, as assumed above, the surplus-value v produced is equal to the average profit. On the other hand, because it [the surplus-value; FM] is equal to the average profit, THE PRICES OF PRODUCTION = COST PRICE + PROFIT = K + P = K + S, which is equal in practice to the commodity's VALUE." (C.III: 309; emphasis added) (Marx discussed this same point about average commodities in Chapter 11 of Volume 3 and in an important letter (April 30, 1868) in which Marx summarized for Engels the main points of Volume 3.) So, Rakesh, I don't think Marx made a mistake in his tables in Chapter 9, when he presented the constant capital (and variable capital) that partly determine the values of commodities as THE SAME MAGNITUDES as the cost price that partly determines the prices of production. This is what Marx assumed about the determination of the value of commodities, and intended to assume: that the transferred value component of the value of commodities is determined by the given money constant capital used to purchase the means of production. The same quantity of constant capital is also taken as given in the determination of prices of production in Volume 3. That is why the constant capital does not have to be transformed in the determination of prices of production. (The same point applies to variable capital as well.) Thanks again for this stimulating discussion. Comradely, Fred
This archive was generated by hypermail 2b29 : Sun Dec 31 2000 - 00:00:04 EST