From: Gerald A. Levy (Gerald_A_Levy@MSN.COM)
Date: Sat Jun 05 2004 - 07:41:31 EDT
By Walt Sheasby. Posted on 6/3/04. Photos in original post./JL COIN AND SYMBOLS OF VALUE: THE LYDIAN INVENTION LYDIAN COINS C. 561-546 BCE Forepart of lion at left with tongue protruding (a Hittite emblem) and of bull at right facing each other. Reverse: Double incuse square, official seal guaranteeing value, standardized at 98% gold or silver. Time of Croesus, king of Lydia, 561-546 BCE. The Greek historian Herodotus (1998: 44) informs us that the Lydians, in Asia Minor, in what is present-day Turkey, first invented coinage around 687 BCE. The earliest coins consisted of electrum, a naturally occurring amalgam of gold and silver, but these were replaced by King Croesus with a coinage of pure gold and silver. By c. 640 - c. 630 BCE, as Herodotus (1.94) noted: *they were the first nation to introduce the use of gold and silver coin, and the first who sold goods by retail.* Herodotus, as pointed out by Roy Davies and Glyn Davies (1999) criticized the avarice of the Lydians, who were not only the first people to coin money, but also, as he said, the first to open permanent retail shops. The account given by Marx assumes familiarity with the classical literature. In the 3rd chapter of Capital on Money, or the Circulation of Commodities, Marx takes up Coin and Symbols of Value: *That money takes the shape of coin, springs from its function as the circulating medium. The weight of gold represented in imagination by the prices or money-names of commodities, must confront those commodities, within the circulation, in the shape of coins or pieces of gold of a given denomination. Coining, like the establishment of a standard of prices, is the business of the State. The different national uniforms worn at home by gold and silver as coins, and doffed again in the market of the world, indicate the separation between the internal or national spheres of the circulation of commodities, and their universal sphere* (221F; 125M). We previously followed his argument that *The money form attaches itself either to the most important articles of exchange from outside, and these in fact are primitive and natural forms in which the exchange value of home products finds expression; or else it attaches itself to the object of utility that forms, like cattle, the chief portion of indigenous alienable wealth* (183F; 92M). As ancient historian Michael Swan and art historian Nicholas Gyenes (2002) explain it, *Cattle were the prized commodity on which the Greek monetary system was based. The Greek islands of Cyprus and Crete during the 16th to 10th centuries B. C. were international trading ports where Assyrians, Mesopotamians, and Egyptians met to trade their goods. With each territory having its own unique currency (Egypt traded in gold, Greece in silver and copper), it was necessary to find a monetary common denominator on which to base trade. The value of an ox was universal in antiquity and became the basis on which all currency was evaluated. A 25.5 g copper ingot, 8.5 g grams of gold were of equal value to a whole ox. This association of monetary values with cattle is well illustrated by the appearance of copper and bronze tablets cut into the shape of ox hides. Coins eventually replaced bars and ingots as currency because they were easier to transport.* From at least 717 to 709 BC, Midas ruled the powerful Phrygian kingdom in what is now central Turkey. Within a few years of the death of Midas c. 680 and the fall of Phrygia, the Lydians, from their capital at Sardis, a city on the Mediterranean coast, moved eastward to fill the void. They expanded eastward until stopped by the Medes at the Halys River. Their state included Ephesus and Miletus and was extended as far as the Aegean. *Under the Mermnads Lydia became a maritime as well as an inland power. The Greek cities were conquered, and the coast of lonia included within the Lydian kingdom. The successes of Alyattes and of Croesus finally changed the Lydian kingdom into a Lydian empire, and all Asia Minor westward of the Halys, except Lycia, owned the supremacy of Sardis* (British Encyclopadedia, 1911).. The electrum coins of Lydia were of two kinds, one weighing 168-4 grains for the inland trade, and another of 224 grains for the trade with Ionia. The Greek cities were allowed to retain their own institutions and government on condition of paying taxes and dues to the Lydian monarch, and the proceeds of their commerce thus flowed into the imperial exchequer. The result was that the king of Lydia became the richest prince of his age. A BRONZE COIN OF SELEUKOS I NIKATOR (c. 313-281 BC) Obverse: Head of Athena wearing Attic helmet. Reverse: Humped bull charging to right http://www.seleukids.org/SeleukosNikator.htm Lydia profited from being on a commercial land route between Mesopotamia and the Aegean and from possessing gold-bearing streams. While the Phrygians had acted as a barrier between the emerging Greek civilization and the civilizations in Mesopotamia and Egypt, the Lydians acted as a bridge. Vast deposits of gold in Lydia near the rivers Galis and Meandros, and the trade on naval and surface ways from Europe to Asia made Lydians a rich people, and this fact encouraged the development of the monarchy here. The Pactolus, which flowed from the fountain of Tame in the Tmolus mountains, through the centre of Sardis, into the Hermus, was believed to be full of golden sand; and gold mines were worked in Tmolus itself (British Encyclopaedia, 1911).. The wealth created by commerce, decreased their interest in defense, and they were defeated by the Persians led by King Cyrus in 546 BCE. Anatolia remained under Persian domination for 200 years until 300 BCE. *Though the Lydians may have invented coinage, it was the Greeks who developed coinage into the main form of exchange and payment across the Mediterranean and beyond* (Shelale). Another aspect of Lydian monetary culture described by Herodotus was their incorporation of sex for money with temple worship, a move that had major ramifications throughout the Mediterranean world. Marx wryly noted: *Temples with the ancients served as the dwellings of the gods of commodities. They were sacred banks. With the Phoenicians, a trading people par excellence, money was the transmuted shape of everything. It was, therefore, quite in order that the virgins, who, at the feast of the Goddess of Love, gave themselves up to strangers, should offer to the goddess the piece of money they received* (Marx, 229F; 132M). In the next installment we look further into the connection of Lydian prostitution with the emergence and evolution of coinage and the growth of sexual slavery. While the footnote by Marx is ironic, it points to a key facet of the evolution of the money-form, and that is the fragmentation, disintegration, and growing stratification of these communities as they blaze the trail for the full-blown commercialized slavery of the later patricians. REFERENCES Map of Ancient Greece/ http://plato-dialogues.org/tools/greece.htm British Encyclopedia (1911), Lydus, the Lydian. http://17.1911encyclopedia.org/L/LY/LYDUS_THE_LYDIAN_JOANNES_LAURENTIUS.htm Davies, Roy and Davies, Glyn (1999), A Comparative Chronology of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day 9,000 - 1 BC. http://www.ex.ac.uk/~RDavies/arian/amser/chrono1.html Marx, Karl, Capital, Vol. 1 (1976), London: Penguin Books; (1987), New York International Publishers. http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch03.htm Shelale (ND), Shelales's Photos, Travels and other Favorites http://www.shelales.com/turkey.htm Swan, Michael and Gyenes, Nicholas (2002), Introduction to Greek Coins http://www.usask.ca/antiquities/coins/greek_coins.html
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Sun Jun 06 2004 - 00:00:01 EDT