From: Paul Cockshott (wpc@DCS.GLA.AC.UK)
Date: Sat Apr 16 2005 - 15:01:25 EDT
Rakesh wrote: But how does this fit with how the late Roman economy which was revolutionized in Banaji's account by securing a stable money--a new gold coinage which provided a means by which financially astute bureaucrats could accumulate fortunes that they subsequently invested in land. Note then Banaji's attempt to rewrite the history of late antiquity--a new currency system in fact assisted the revival and indeed an expansion of a monetized economy. Paul Cockshott As far as I can determine this is the subject of lively debate among economic historians of the roman empire. I regret to say that having just read a collection of papers on the subject last month I realize that I have failed to note the sources which argue that the evidence for trends in price levels in the second and 3rd centuries supported the chartalist theory. The argument basically was that the debasement of the denarius should have created a far worse inflation than it actually did. Can you please give me a ref to the work by Banaji that you are relying on? > >This local and temporary historical phenomena is universalised >in metallist doctrines. What seems to me implied here is another explanation for one thing enjoying a monopoly over direct exchangeability. If I understand you Paul correctly, you are saying that thing does so as the singular medium through which the state collects taxes. Money thus represents the power of the state and in virtue of that becomes the singular representative of abstract social labor time. But does it matter for Marx's argument how that one thing comes to be the sole representative of abstract social labor time, for once it is that for whatever reason it then has the power to interrupt circulation, to become the object of hoarding? And it is hoarded not as the medium through which taxes will have to be paid but as the sole representative of abstract social labor time. rb ----------- Paul Cockshott In one way you are right. However money came to be the representation of power over labour, the consequences for the analysis of the circuit of capital do not change much. On the other hand it is important for analyzing the role of money as a store of value and for anlaysing the revenues of the state. In a monetary economy the state has two was of gaining access to real labour resources. 1 It can levy a tax in money and spend the money buying labour or commodities. 2 It can simply mint and spend the money. This process is termed seigneurage. Taxation and seigneurage are mutually inter-dependent. Unless there is an intial minting of money, no tax in money can be levied. On the other hand if no taxes are levied, then the money will be valueless and the state will be unable to appropriate real resouces with its coin. In a natural economy the appropriation of resouces by the state is direct and constrained by its political ability to coerce property owners into handing over goods, and also to coerce subjects into performing labour services. With the invention of money, the appropriation of a surplus splits into two - a symbolic appropriation of coins as tax goes alongside a real appropriation, by purchase, of labour time and commodities. The real appropriation appears as something equitable and voluntary. The coercive aspect of the process occurs entirely in the realm of symbols - rendering unto Ceasar that which is Ceasar's. Coercion remains bounded by political ability. Taxation meets resistance whether it occurs in money or kind. But because there is a split between the real and symbolic domains, seigneurage can act as a wedge to force them appart. A state can, within limits, appropriate more labour than it can raise symbolically as tax. Taxation is a recurrent process. It provides a stream of symbolic labour to be spent on real labour. Seigneurage is a one off process needed to start the tax process going. In the year the coins are minted, the Crown can purchase more than it taxes. This acts as a constant temptation for states whose tax raising power is weak, for minting coin is politically easier than raising taxes. The issue of coin has to be a continuous process anyway. a) There is always a certain loss of coin due to accident or ware and tear. The subject's accidental loss is the Crown's gain. If a coin falls in a river, a record that services have been performed for the Crown goes with it. If taxes are to be met, the Crown must issue a new coin, and the subjects must perform new services to get it. This means that a certain level of seigneurage is built into the system. This seigneurage derives from the {\em lost information} caused by the imperfections of coin as a technology of record. b) Some additional minting is required to keep pace with the growth in the value of commodity circulation. As more people are drawn into commodity production - because of population growth, the expansion of the state, or because previously natural economic processes become commodified - then more coin is required to sustain this trade. c) Hoarding or saving withdraws coin from circulation. Of course many hoards are eventually lost either for ever, or to be found by archeologists centuries later. But leaving those aside for the moment, the effect of hoarding is very similar to that of loss from the standpoint of the state. If a hoarder puts away 100 coins a year into a hoard, then, unless these are compensated for by other hoaders dissipating their hoards, the Crown can issue an extra 100 coins per year. Any net hoarding by the population allows a cooresponding rise in the annual issue of coin. The consequence of a higher issue, is more seignurage - real appropriation of labour and services by the Crown. But the money form hides this, both from holders of money, and from some economists who should know better. Open an elementary economics textbook and you read that money serves as a store of value. Hoarders believed this, but it is fundamentally an illusion. A miser with 1000 pennies under the floor, had not stored up value: he buried the ghost of value departed. The King issued pennies in return for real value - work. Like as not, they were born as soldier's pay. Then the work of soldiering, like winter's snow, vanished leaving no material residue. Aside from the paltry scrap value of Royal cannon, no vendible commodity survived, What the miser stored was information, a number that assigned to him a tiny fraction of the power royal. Should he spend his hoard he would command the labour of others. But should all hoarders try to do this at once, they found themselves competing with the normal purchasors of labour and commodities. Prices would go up. The social power represented by each coin would fall. In time of famine hoards were spent. They helped ensure the survival of the hoarders, but only by grabbing them a larger share of a diminished crop. They redistribute starvation, but on a social scale do not represent an accumulation of value. A social provision against famine could only occur if there were a real accumulation of value in the form of corn in granaries. This obviously has contemporary relevance in the current political debates about privatized pension provision.
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Tue Apr 19 2005 - 00:00:02 EDT