From: glevy@PRATT.EDU
Date: Fri Jan 13 2006 - 06:07:41 EST
Another 2 items from the Heterodox Economics Newsletter-21 =========================================================== Paolo Sylos Labini Dear friends, I am writing to give you the sad news that Paolo Sylos Labini passed away yesterday in Rome, after a short illness. I am sure you remember him as a great economist, a fighter of many causes and a kind and generous person. With kind regards, Cristina Prof. Maria Cristina Marcuzzo Direttore del Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche Paolo Sylos Labini: un economista eretico? La notizia della morte di Paolo Sylos Labini non può che rattristare tutti coloro che ne apprezzavano le capacità teoriche, scientifiche, espositive e la grandissima verve polemica, negli ultimi anni rivolta particolarmente contro Berlusconi (si veda ad esempio l'interessante e per certi aspetti divertente, "Un paese a civiltà limitata", libro-intervista pubblicato nel 2001 per i tipi di Laterza). Del resto sono ancora oggi molto importanti i suoi studi sulle tendenze oligopolistiche del capitalismo, sui rapporti tra sviluppo e progresso tecnico, sui ceti medi; volumi ricchi di osservazioni interessanti e di senso storico e sociologico. Si può ritenere che Sylos Labini sia stato dopo Pareto il primo economista italiano a occuparsi seriamente dell' evoluzione delle classi medie. Quel che però non convince, e basta dare un'occhiata ai "coccodrilli" apparsi ieri sui giornali, è la pretesa di considerarlo un eretico. Su questo giudizio non si può essere d'accordo. Perché? In primo luogo, Sylos Labini fu allievo negli Stati Uniti di Schumpeter, grande e tragico profeta (ma anche apologeta) del capitalismo. Un'esperienza che lasciò su di lui segni indelebili. Infatti, fin dai primi suoi lavori (cfr. la voce "investimenti", nel "Dizionario di economia" a cura di Napoleoni - 1956, pp. 765-793), Sylos Labini, sulla scia di Schumpeter, non si è mai stancato di ripetere che il capitalismo, pur con le sue manchevolezze (burocratizzazioni, oligopoli, rendite parassitarie) resta sempre il migliore dei mondi possibili: l'unico scenario economico capace di favorire gli investimenti e dunque di promuovere lo sviluppo umano nella democrazia. In secondo luogo, anche l'importanza che nella sua opera ha assunto l'innovazione teconologica "creatrice" in rapporto allo sviluppo non solo sociale ma produttivo, testimonia quanto l'interpretazione schumpeteriana del capitalismo, come forza creatrice e distruttrice al tempo stesso, abbia pesato sullo sviluppo del suo pensiero. In terzo luogo, il problema dell' innovazione resta in lui legato, come del resto anche in Schumpeter, a quello della funzione imprenditoriale. Di qui la sua critica alle forme di imprenditoria semipubblica, parassitarie e nemiche delle regole di mercato, che secondo l'economista italiano, sono splendidamente illustrate, e per sempre racchiuse, nella "Ricchezza delle Nazioni" di Adam Smith. In quarto luogo, il rapporto Sylos Labini-Marx è piuttosto controverso. L'economista italiano ne sempre ammirato più la sociologia che l'economia (il collegamento tra economia capitalista e classi sociali), ma di Marx non ha mai condiviso due tesi: quella sulla caduta del saggio di profitto e quella sull' impoverimento bipolare delle classi sociali. Ora, proprio per queste ragioni (sostanzialmente: il muoversi teoricamente all'interno della visione schumpeteriana del capitalismo), Paolo Sylos Labini non può essere considerato un eretico. O comunque non nel senso che oggi viene dato a questo termine. Detto in breve Sylos Labini è per la "crescita" e non per la "decrescita". Tutta la sua opera è un elogio dell' innovazione produttiva e dello sviluppo economico indefinto, come solo strumento per redistribuire la ricchezza. Questo spiega, ma è solo una curiosità, perché la bibbia dell'economia eterodossa il "Biographical Dictionary of Dissenting Economists" (Elgar 1992, 2000 www.e-elgar.com) non gli abbia dedicato alcuna voce. Dispiace ma è così. By Carlo Gambescia On behalf of ESHET, I send an obituary of Paolo Sylos Labini, elected as Honorary Member of the society. Daniele Besomi Paolo Sylos Labini passed away on December 7th, 2005, aged 85. Emeritus Professor at the University La Sapienza (Rome) and one of the most eminent economists in the world, he was known for his seminal theory of oligopoly and many other contributions. His book Oligopolio e progresso tecnico (1956) is a milestone in the history of economics. He has left us many important studies about economic development and its determinants, nearly all of them translated into English. His last book, published a few months ago, goes back to his preferred theme of development and technical progress and to his preferred approach: the history of economics as a way to understand present problems. Its title is: Torniamo ai classici. Produttivite del lavoro, progresso tecnico e sviluppo economico, Roma-Bari: Laterza, 2005 (Let's go back to the Classics. Labour productivity, technical progress and economic development). After graduation, Sylos Labini studied at Harvard, with Joseph Schumpeter, and in Cambridge (UK); he was member of some of the most prestigious academies and scientific associations, in Italy (among which the Accademia dei Lincei ) and in the world (among which the American Economic Association). He also was awarded many prestigious scientific prizes, and was repeatedly called to advise the Italian government and other policy institutions. At the last ESHET Conference, in Stirling, the Council awarded him the title of Honorary Member, with the following motivation:"Sylos Labini is an eminent scholar of economics always interested in the history of economics. His studies on oligopolistic markets, on development and underdevelopment, and on social classes cannot be really detached from his interests in the Classical school, in the value theory, in the economics of underdevelopment and especially in Adam Smith�s thought. Beside giving us a deep insight in these problems, Sylos Labini has thought us a scientific approach free from ideologies, independent but also socially engaged." When I officially informed him of the award, his reaction was:"I am really pleased about this title of Honorary Member of ESHET. Please convey to the Council and the Executive Committee my feelings of real happiness. It will be a great pleasure for me to attend the Dinner in Porto, provided that I am still around!" (my translation from Italian). Probably he felt his end near, but hinted at it with much sobriety. He was disenchanted with human nature and social injustice, and nevertheless passionately fought for social development and justice at a scientific and a civic level. In times dominated by ideologies, even in economics, he stood for an empirical approach, looking for rational ways to promote economic development and defending the often neglected role of technical progress. He did not like grand theories about human nature. He preferred to "measure" factors of production and cultural attitudes, without losing sight of the social and moral values. This is how he repeatedly approached issues like social classes in Italy, underdevelopment, industrial relations and the development of Southern Italy. The language of his research was simple and straightforward; the concepts were neat and clear, free from any rhetoric. Thanks to his disinterested commitment to science and to society, Paolo Sylos Labini was exceptionally able to stir human sympathy. His life is a remarkable example of how scientific engagement and civic commitment can be combined without prejudicing their reciprocal independence. Cosimo Perrotta ================================================================== Rudolf Meidner, 1914 - 2005: A Visonary Pragmatist By ROBIN BLACKBURN Rudolf Meidner, chief economist of the LO, Sweden's largest trade union federation, and an immensely practical socialist visionary, died in December. If Meidner had not been a Swedish citizen, and still a controversial figure at the age of 91, he would very likely have been awarded the Nobel Prize for economics. Meidner was, after all, the co-architect -- with Gosta Rehn -- of the Swedish welfare state, an achievement which, by itself, would have merited such a nomination. Those responsible for this prize tend to prefer theory to policy but it should be clear to everyone that the Rehn/Meidner model was based on its own distinctive theoretical insights and that policy-oriented economics is anyway deserving of recognition. Building on Keynes and James Meade, the two men understood that welfare and corporate finance needed to be thought through together if high employment levels were to be maintained and inflation avoided. Remarkably enough, their model did for long succeed in delivering on both fronts -- something which, sadly, cannot be said about other European welfare states, where monetary stability was achieved at the expense of a long and debilitating toleration of high levels of unemployment, with younger workers, older workers and ethnic minorities the worst affected. From the time of the introduction of the second pension system, the ATP, in 1959 the 'Swedish home' could accumulate a trust fund so that in future asset income as well as current taxes could be drawn on to pay ATP entitlements. Continental European pension systems were more purely reliant on pay-as-you-go. The famous wage-bargaining round was another device which Rehn and Meidner integrated into their model, helping it to avoid the twin perils of hyperinflation and persistent, high joblessness. Meidner's position as the chief economist of the LO, the main trade union federation, must have been important in promoting a species of solidaristic wage-bargaining in which the fruits of productivity advances were widely shared. In recent years the Netherlands has had good results with a similar approach. Another crucial mechanism for maintaining macro-economic balance in the Rehn/Meidner model was the investment reserve. Whereas Anglo-Saxon companies are encouraged to take 'contribution holidays' -- and put nothing into their pension and health-care funds during upswings of the business cycle -- Swedish corporations were encouraged to stow operating profits in special tax-exempt reserves. More generally the Swedish welfare state guaranteed secondary pensions and health care to all citizens, instead of offering private corporations tax incentives to take on the task of supplying social insurance to their own workers. The latter formula -- Anglo-Saxon style corporate welfare -- has proved to be a trap for employees, depriving them of their promised benefits and threatening their jobs as once-famous companies plunge into bankruptcy and entire industries -- steel, airlines, auto and telecoms -- are ravaged by the burden of pension and health entitlements. The corporate pensions crunch destroys good jobs and their replacement by low-wage, insecure service employment -- MacJobs-- is scant compensation. I am aware that Sweden's welfare state and social market economy faced its own near-collapse in the early 1990s and that the Rehn/Meidner model did not emerge unscathed. This crisis was deemed to reflect badly on the model though both Rehn and Meidner had stepped down long before, and their advice had anyway not been heeded. Looking back over three or four decades, there remains something very distinctive about the Swedish achievement, something which owes much to the original model. Swedish welfare remains comparatively generous and Swedish unemployment only a little over a half of the core EU rate. Swedish parents have access to better child-care, and Swedish women have better-paying and more flexible jobs than are to be found in other advanced countries. Meidner's achievement goes beyond his role, important as that was, in helping to set up the 'Swedish home'. He saw that an ageing and learning society would require social expenditure on a scale unprecedented in peacetime (one could easily add such challenges as ecological degradation and climate change). Meidner came to believe in the need to establish strategic social funds -- 'wage-earner funds' - to be financed by a share levy. The huge controversy which was provoked by this proposal generated more heat than light. The Social Democratic party leadership did not share Meidner's vision and did a poor job of presenting it to the Swedish people. Meidner's plan was very radical and they were not. With hindsight there were aspects of the plan that needed adjustment but those made by the SAPD went in the wrong direction. Having, as they saw it, burnt their fingers, the Social Democratic leaders began to see Meidner as an embarrassment, or as a relic of a by-gone age. He was consigned to the shadows and no part of his thinking was more disdained than the 'wage-earner funds'. Yet financing pensions, research and education becomes increasingly difficult throughout the OECD countries. Does it really make sense to pay for public programmes only out of current tax revenues and not to pre-fund them, or to introduce even the most modest tax on shareholding wealth. It is a striking fact that while most governments are happy to tax the homes people live in, they all refuse to have any direct levy on share-holding wealth or to allow -- as Meidner boldly imagined -- social funds to exercise control over the large corporations. Increasingly, it seems, we live in a society like the French Ancièn Regime before 1789. Then the wealth of the feudal aristocracy was largely exempt from tax; now it is the holdings of the corporate millionaires and billionaires that escape taxation. Other signs reminiscent of the age of Louis XVI include the spirit of 'après nous le deluge', the reliance on lotteries, and the emergence of modern variants of 'tax farming' -- for example, laws which oblige citizens to pay their taxes (pension contributions) to commercial fund managers rather than to an accountable public body. But the taboo on effective taxation of corporate wealth is the most crucial sign of the reign of privilege. Rudolf Meidner's share levy, unlike so many modern taxes, was extraordinarily difficult to evade. On the other hand it was not at all punitive. Unlike traditional corporate taxation, it did not subtract from the cash-flow or resources which the enterprise needed for investment. It diluted shareholder wealth without weakening the corporation as a productive concern. According to the original plan every company with more than fifty employees was obliged to issue new shares every year equivalent to 20 per cent of its profits. The newly issued shares -- which could not be sold -- were to be given to the network of 'wage earner funds', representing workplaces and local authorities. The latter would hold the shares, and reinvest the income they yielded from dividends, in order to finance future social expenditure. As the wage earner funds grew they would be able to play an increasing part in directing policy in the corporations which they owned. The idea that workers ands citizens should tame the corporations by establishing control of financial instruments was an echo of ideas that Meidner imbibed in his youth from the debates of German and Austrian Marxian economists like Rudolf Hilferding and Karl Polanyi. For Meidner was not born in Sweden but arrived there as a refugee in 1938. Meidner's visionary scheme was warmly welcomed by many trade unions and by members of the Social Democratic party but strongly opposed by the press and by the '20 families' who then dominated the country's large corporations. It was adopted by the LO in 1976 and, much more cautiously, by the Social Democrats a couple of years later. Opponents of the scheme, claimed that it would aggrandize the trade unions who would dominate the 'wage-earner funds'. It was also alleged that the scheme unfairly favoured employees in the private sector since they were to be the first to receive shares from the levy. Scare campaigns persuaded the governing Social Democratic not simply to reduce the size of the levy -- 10 per cent of profits would have been a perfectly good starting point -- but to abandon the principle of the levy itself. Likewise they did not improve the funds' accountability but instead prevented them from having any say in corporate policy. By 1992 even the scaled-down social funds owned 7 per cent of the Swedish stock market but, to prevent them getting any larger, were wound up by the Conservatives in 1992 and the proceeds used to finance a string of scientific research institutes. So Meidner's plan has yet to be properly tried, though even in its diluted form the social funds helped to propel Sweden to the forefront of the knowledge-based economy. Rudolph Meidner, as a radical social democrat, an egalitarian and an organic intellectual of the labour movement was committed to a 'third way' that was actually the antithesis of the doctrine of that name subsequently espoused by Tony Blair. Were Blair is vague and rhetorical, Meidner was precise and institutionally specific. Where Blair encourages the privatization and commodification of everything, Meidner was dedicated to the 'de-commodification' of welfare, education and research. And his proposal for a network of regional funds broke with the traditional socialist practice of concentrating more power in the central state. It is now a long time since governments of the Left have dared to tried to tame the corporations and ask whether the owners of the large corporations might be obliged to contribute more to the wider society, without which their own profits would be impossible. The most far-sighted attempt to think through the types of new finance that would be needed to guarantee generous social provision remains that of Rudolf Meidner and this will be his legacy to the 21st century. Robin Blackburn is Visiting Distinguished Professor at the New School for Social Resaerch in New York and professor of sociology at the University of Essex, UK. He is the author of Banking on Death: the History and Future of Pensions
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Tue Jan 17 2006 - 00:00:01 EST