Re: [OPE-L] the deaths of Paolo Sylos Labini and Rudolf Meidner

From: Cyrus Bina (binac@MORRIS.UMN.EDU)
Date: Mon Jan 16 2006 - 14:34:15 EST


Dear All;

This is indeed a great loss for the political economy as a whole and
certainly for many of us who appreciate Paolo Sylos Labini's pioneering
work on competition and monopoly.

Cyrus

glevy@PRATT.EDU wrote:

>Another 2 items from the Heterodox Economics Newsletter-21
>
>===========================================================
>
>
>
>      Paolo Sylos Labini
>
>      Dear friends,
>      I am writing to give you the sad news that Paolo Sylos Labini passed
>away yesterday in Rome, after a short illness.
>      I am sure you remember him as a great economist, a fighter of many
>causes and a kind and generous person.
>      With kind regards,
>      Cristina
>      Prof. Maria Cristina Marcuzzo
>      Direttore del Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche
>
>      Paolo Sylos Labini: un economista eretico?
>      La notizia della morte di Paolo Sylos Labini non può che rattristare
>tutti coloro che ne apprezzavano le capacità teoriche, scientifiche,
>espositive e la grandissima verve polemica, negli ultimi anni
>rivolta particolarmente contro Berlusconi (si veda ad esempio
>l'interessante e per certi aspetti divertente, "Un paese a civiltà
>limitata", libro-intervista pubblicato nel 2001 per i tipi di
>Laterza).
>      Del resto sono ancora oggi molto importanti i suoi studi sulle
>tendenze oligopolistiche del capitalismo, sui rapporti tra sviluppo
>e progresso tecnico, sui ceti medi; volumi ricchi di osservazioni
>interessanti e di senso storico e sociologico. Si può ritenere che
>Sylos Labini sia stato dopo Pareto il primo economista italiano a
>occuparsi seriamente dell' evoluzione delle classi medie.
>      Quel che però non convince, e basta dare un'occhiata ai
>"coccodrilli" apparsi ieri sui giornali, è la pretesa di
>considerarlo un eretico. Su questo giudizio non si può essere
>d'accordo. Perché?
>      In primo luogo, Sylos Labini fu allievo negli Stati Uniti di
>Schumpeter, grande e tragico profeta (ma anche apologeta) del
>capitalismo. Un'esperienza che lasciò su di lui segni indelebili.
>Infatti, fin dai primi suoi lavori (cfr. la voce "investimenti", nel
>"Dizionario di economia" a cura di Napoleoni - 1956, pp. 765-793),
>Sylos Labini, sulla scia di Schumpeter, non si è mai stancato di
>ripetere che il capitalismo, pur con le sue manchevolezze
>(burocratizzazioni, oligopoli, rendite parassitarie) resta sempre il
>migliore dei mondi possibili: l'unico scenario economico capace di
>favorire gli investimenti e dunque di promuovere lo sviluppo umano
>nella democrazia.
>      In secondo luogo, anche l'importanza che nella sua opera ha assunto
>l'innovazione teconologica "creatrice" in rapporto allo sviluppo non
>solo sociale ma produttivo, testimonia quanto l'interpretazione
>schumpeteriana del capitalismo, come forza creatrice e distruttrice
>al tempo stesso, abbia pesato sullo sviluppo del suo pensiero.
>      In terzo luogo, il problema dell' innovazione resta in lui legato,
>come del resto anche in Schumpeter, a quello della funzione
>imprenditoriale. Di qui la sua critica alle forme di imprenditoria
>semipubblica, parassitarie e nemiche delle regole di mercato, che
>secondo l'economista italiano, sono splendidamente illustrate, e per
>sempre racchiuse, nella "Ricchezza delle Nazioni" di Adam Smith.
>      In quarto luogo, il rapporto Sylos Labini-Marx è piuttosto
>controverso. L'economista italiano ne sempre ammirato più la
>sociologia che l'economia (il collegamento tra economia capitalista
>e classi sociali), ma di Marx non ha mai condiviso due tesi: quella
>sulla caduta del saggio di profitto e quella sull' impoverimento
>bipolare delle classi sociali.
>      Ora, proprio per queste ragioni (sostanzialmente: il muoversi
>teoricamente all'interno della visione schumpeteriana del
>capitalismo), Paolo Sylos Labini non può essere considerato un
>eretico. O comunque non nel senso che oggi viene dato a questo
>termine. Detto in breve Sylos Labini è per la "crescita" e non per
>la "decrescita". Tutta la sua opera è un elogio dell' innovazione
>produttiva e dello sviluppo economico indefinto, come solo strumento
>per redistribuire la ricchezza.
>      Questo spiega, ma è solo una curiosità, perché la bibbia
>dell'economia eterodossa il "Biographical Dictionary of Dissenting
>Economists" (Elgar 1992, 2000 www.e-elgar.com) non gli abbia
>dedicato alcuna voce.
>      Dispiace ma è così.
>
>      By Carlo Gambescia
>
>      On behalf of ESHET, I send an obituary of Paolo Sylos Labini,
>elected as Honorary Member of the society. Daniele Besomi
>
>      Paolo Sylos Labini passed away on December 7th, 2005, aged 85.
>Emeritus Professor at the University La Sapienza (Rome) and one of
>the most eminent economists in the world, he was known for his
>seminal theory of oligopoly and many other contributions. His book
>Oligopolio e progresso tecnico (1956) is a milestone in the history
>of economics. He has left us many important studies about economic
>development and its determinants, nearly all of them translated into
>English. His last book, published a few months ago, goes back to his
>preferred theme of development and technical progress and to his
>preferred approach: the history of economics as a way to understand
>present problems. Its title is: Torniamo ai classici. Produttivite
>del lavoro, progresso tecnico e sviluppo economico, Roma-Bari:
>Laterza, 2005 (Let's go back to the Classics. Labour productivity,
>technical progress and economic development).
>
>      After graduation, Sylos Labini studied at Harvard, with Joseph
>Schumpeter, and in Cambridge (UK); he was member of some of the most
>prestigious academies and scientific associations, in Italy (among
>which the Accademia dei Lincei ) and in the world (among which the
>American Economic Association). He also was awarded many prestigious
>scientific prizes, and was repeatedly called to advise the Italian
>government and other policy institutions.
>
>      At the last ESHET Conference, in Stirling, the Council awarded him
>the title of Honorary Member, with the following motivation:"Sylos
>Labini is an eminent scholar of economics always interested in the
>history of economics. His studies on oligopolistic markets, on
>development and underdevelopment, and on social classes cannot be
>really detached from his interests in the Classical school, in the
>value theory, in the economics of underdevelopment and especially in
>Adam Smith�s thought. Beside giving us a deep insight in these
>problems, Sylos Labini has thought us a scientific approach free
>from ideologies, independent but also socially engaged."
>
>      When I officially informed him of the award, his reaction was:"I am
>really pleased about this title of Honorary Member of ESHET. Please
>convey to the Council and the Executive Committee my feelings of
>real happiness. It will be a great pleasure for me to attend the
>Dinner in Porto, provided that I am still around!" (my translation
>from Italian).
>      Probably he felt his end near, but hinted at it with much sobriety.
>He was disenchanted with human nature and social injustice, and
>nevertheless passionately fought for social development and justice
>at a scientific and a civic level. In times dominated by ideologies,
>even in economics, he stood for an empirical approach, looking for
>rational ways to promote economic development and defending the
>often neglected role of technical progress. He did not like grand
>theories about human nature. He preferred to "measure" factors of
>production and cultural attitudes, without losing sight of the
>social and moral values. This is how he repeatedly approached issues
>like social classes in Italy, underdevelopment, industrial relations
>and the development of Southern Italy.
>
>      The language of his research was simple and straightforward; the
>concepts were neat and clear, free from any rhetoric. Thanks to his
>disinterested commitment to science and to society, Paolo Sylos
>Labini was exceptionally able to stir human sympathy. His life is a
>remarkable example of how scientific engagement and civic commitment
>can be combined without prejudicing their reciprocal independence.
>
>      Cosimo Perrotta
>
>==================================================================
>
>
>
>
>      Rudolf Meidner, 1914 - 2005: A Visonary Pragmatist
>
>      By ROBIN BLACKBURN
>
>      Rudolf Meidner, chief economist of the LO, Sweden's largest trade
>union federation, and an immensely practical socialist visionary,
>died in December. If Meidner had not been a Swedish citizen, and
>still a controversial figure at the age of 91, he would very likely
>have been awarded the Nobel Prize for economics. Meidner was, after
>all, the co-architect -- with Gosta Rehn -- of the Swedish welfare
>state, an achievement which, by itself, would have merited such a
>nomination.
>      Those responsible for this prize tend to prefer theory to policy but
>it should be clear to everyone that the Rehn/Meidner model was based
>on its own distinctive theoretical insights and that policy-oriented
>economics is anyway deserving of recognition.
>
>      Building on Keynes and James Meade, the two men understood that
>welfare and corporate finance needed to be thought through together
>if high employment levels were to be maintained and inflation
>avoided.
>      Remarkably enough, their model did for long succeed in delivering on
>both fronts -- something which, sadly, cannot be said about other
>European welfare states, where monetary stability was achieved at
>the expense of a long and debilitating toleration of high levels of
>unemployment, with younger workers, older workers and ethnic
>minorities the worst affected.
>
>      From the time of the introduction of the second pension system, the
>ATP, in 1959 the 'Swedish home' could accumulate a trust fund so
>that in future asset income as well as current taxes could be drawn
>on to pay ATP entitlements. Continental European pension systems
>were more purely reliant on pay-as-you-go. The famous
>wage-bargaining round was another device which Rehn and Meidner
>integrated into their model, helping it to avoid the twin perils of
>hyperinflation and persistent, high joblessness. Meidner's position
>as the chief economist of the LO, the main trade union federation,
>must have been important in promoting a species of solidaristic
>wage-bargaining in which the fruits of productivity advances were
>widely shared. In recent years the Netherlands has had good results
>with a similar approach.
>
>      Another crucial mechanism for maintaining macro-economic balance in
>the Rehn/Meidner model was the investment reserve. Whereas
>Anglo-Saxon companies are encouraged to take 'contribution holidays'
>-- and put nothing into their pension and health-care funds during
>upswings of the business cycle -- Swedish corporations were
>encouraged to stow operating profits in special tax-exempt reserves.
>More generally the Swedish welfare state guaranteed secondary
>pensions and health care to all citizens, instead of offering
>private corporations tax incentives to take on the task of supplying
>social insurance to their own workers. The latter formula --
>Anglo-Saxon style corporate welfare -- has proved to be a trap for
>employees, depriving them of their promised benefits and threatening
>their jobs as once-famous companies plunge into bankruptcy and
>entire industries -- steel, airlines, auto and telecoms -- are
>ravaged by the burden of pension and health entitlements. The
>corporate pensions crunch destroys good jobs and their replacement
>by low-wage, insecure service employment -- MacJobs-- is scant
>compensation.
>
>      I am aware that Sweden's welfare state and social market economy
>faced its own near-collapse in the early 1990s and that the
>Rehn/Meidner model did not emerge unscathed. This crisis was deemed
>to reflect badly on the model though both Rehn and Meidner had
>stepped down long before, and their advice had anyway not been
>heeded. Looking back over three or four decades, there remains
>something very distinctive about the Swedish achievement, something
>which owes much to the original model. Swedish welfare remains
>comparatively generous and Swedish unemployment only a little over a
>half of the core EU rate. Swedish parents have access to better
>child-care, and Swedish women have better-paying and more flexible
>jobs than are to be found in other advanced countries.
>
>      Meidner's achievement goes beyond his role, important as that was,
>in helping to set up the 'Swedish home'. He saw that an ageing and
>learning society would require social expenditure on a scale
>unprecedented in peacetime (one could easily add such challenges as
>ecological degradation and climate change). Meidner came to believe
>in the need to establish strategic social funds -- 'wage-earner
>funds' - to be financed by a share levy. The huge controversy which
>was provoked by this proposal generated more heat than light.
>
>      The Social Democratic party leadership did not share Meidner's
>vision and did a poor job of presenting it to the Swedish people.
>Meidner's plan was very radical and they were not. With hindsight
>there were aspects of the plan that needed adjustment but those made
>by the SAPD went in the wrong direction. Having, as they saw it,
>burnt their fingers, the Social Democratic leaders began to see
>Meidner as an embarrassment, or as a relic of a by-gone age. He was
>consigned to the shadows and no part of his thinking was more
>disdained than the 'wage-earner funds'.
>
>      Yet financing pensions, research and education becomes increasingly
>difficult throughout the OECD countries. Does it really make sense
>to pay for public programmes only out of current tax revenues and
>not to pre-fund them, or to introduce even the most modest tax on
>shareholding wealth. It is a striking fact that while most
>governments are happy to tax the homes people live in, they all
>refuse to have any direct levy on share-holding wealth or to allow
>-- as Meidner boldly imagined -- social funds to exercise control
>over the large corporations.
>
>      Increasingly, it seems, we live in a society like the French Ancièn
>Regime before 1789. Then the wealth of the feudal aristocracy was
>largely exempt from tax; now it is the holdings of the corporate
>millionaires and billionaires that escape taxation. Other signs
>reminiscent of the age of Louis XVI include the spirit of 'après
>nous le deluge', the reliance on lotteries, and the emergence of
>modern variants of 'tax farming' -- for example, laws which oblige
>citizens to pay their taxes (pension contributions) to commercial
>fund managers rather than to an accountable public body. But the
>taboo on effective taxation of corporate wealth is the most crucial
>sign of the reign of privilege.
>
>      Rudolf Meidner's share levy, unlike so many modern taxes, was
>extraordinarily difficult to evade. On the other hand it was not at
>all punitive. Unlike traditional corporate taxation, it did not
>subtract from the cash-flow or resources which the enterprise needed
>for investment. It diluted shareholder wealth without weakening the
>corporation as a productive concern. According to the original plan
>every company with more than fifty employees was obliged to issue
>new shares every year equivalent to 20 per cent of its profits. The
>newly issued shares -- which could not be sold -- were to be given
>to the network of 'wage earner funds', representing workplaces and
>local authorities. The latter would hold the shares, and reinvest
>the income they yielded from dividends, in order to finance future
>social expenditure. As the wage earner funds grew they would be able
>to play an increasing part in directing policy in the corporations
>which they owned.
>
>      The idea that workers ands citizens should tame the corporations by
>establishing control of financial instruments was an echo of ideas
>that Meidner imbibed in his youth from the debates of German and
>Austrian Marxian economists like Rudolf Hilferding and Karl Polanyi.
>      For Meidner was not born in Sweden but arrived there as a refugee in
>1938.
>
>      Meidner's visionary scheme was warmly welcomed by many trade unions
>and by members of the Social Democratic party but strongly opposed
>by the press and by the '20 families' who then dominated the
>country's large corporations. It was adopted by the LO in 1976 and,
>much more cautiously, by the Social Democrats a couple of years
>later.
>      Opponents of the scheme, claimed that it would aggrandize the trade
>unions who would dominate the 'wage-earner funds'. It was also
>alleged that the scheme unfairly favoured employees in the private
>sector since they were to be the first to receive shares from the
>levy. Scare campaigns persuaded the governing Social Democratic not
>simply to reduce the size of the levy -- 10 per cent of profits
>would have been a perfectly good starting point -- but to abandon
>the principle of the levy itself. Likewise they did not improve the
>funds' accountability but instead prevented them from having any say
>in corporate policy. By
>      1992 even the scaled-down social funds owned 7 per cent of the
>Swedish stock market but, to prevent them getting any larger, were
>wound up by the Conservatives in 1992 and the proceeds used to
>finance a string of scientific research institutes. So Meidner's
>plan has yet to be properly tried, though even in its diluted form
>the social funds helped to propel Sweden to the forefront of the
>knowledge-based economy.
>
>      Rudolph Meidner, as a radical social democrat, an egalitarian and an
>organic intellectual of the labour movement was committed to a
>'third way' that was actually the antithesis of the doctrine of that
>name subsequently espoused by Tony Blair. Were Blair is vague and
>rhetorical, Meidner was precise and institutionally specific. Where
>Blair encourages the privatization and commodification of
>everything, Meidner was dedicated to the 'de-commodification' of
>welfare, education and research. And his proposal for a network of
>regional funds broke with the traditional socialist practice of
>concentrating more power in the central state.
>
>      It is now a long time since governments of the Left have dared to
>tried to tame the corporations and ask whether the owners of the
>large corporations might be obliged to contribute more to the wider
>society, without which their own profits would be impossible. The
>most far-sighted attempt to think through the types of new finance
>that would be needed to guarantee generous social provision remains
>that of Rudolf Meidner and this will be his legacy to the 21st
>century.
>
>      Robin Blackburn is Visiting Distinguished Professor at the New
>School for Social Resaerch in New York and professor of sociology at
>the University of Essex, UK. He is the author of Banking on Death:
>the History and Future of Pensions
>
>


This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Tue Jan 17 2006 - 00:00:01 EST